MIM(Prisons) is a cell of revolutionaries serving the oppressed masses inside U.$. prisons, guided by the communist ideology of Marxism-Leninism-Maoism.
Under Lock & Key is a news service written by and for prisoners with a focus on what is going on behind bars throughout the United States. Under Lock & Key is available to U.S. prisoners for free through MIM(Prisons)'s Free Political Literature to Prisoners Program, by writing:
MIM(Prisons) PO Box 40799 San Francisco, CA 94140.
From Victory to Defeat: China’s Socialist Road
and Capitalist Reversal
by Pao-Yu Ching
Foreign Languages Press
2019
In a recent online debate between two random “Marxist-Leninists” and
two fascists, one of the self-described “Marxist-Leninists” stated that
every country in the last 100 years has been socialist. The fascists are
happy to parade such meaningless dribble as “Marxism” so that they can
make Marxism look bad. With Obama’s election, white nationalist fear
became expressed in many derogatory words, including “communism” and
“Marxism,” with no sense of irony that they were accusing the number one
enemy of the world’s people of being a communist.
What is common among “Marxists” in the First World is saying every
country is socialist that says it is and has some form of state
intervention in the economy. This superficial analysis has also helped
muddy the water of what socialism is. And it allows the fascists to say
that they share many of the goals and ideals of the self-described
Marxists. In particular they both look to China as a positive model of
how to run a country and they both think Amerikans and various First
World European nations are being victimized by the current world system.
The fact that many of these fascists have chauvinist anti-Chinese views
and wish war against the social-imperialist CPC is of no matter. For
MIM, the question of whether today’s China is socialist or
social-imperialist is a dividing line question.
To understand what socialism is, MIM has long recommended The
Chinese Road to Socialism by Wheelright and MacFarlane. For the
history of the coup that overthrew socialism in China MIM distributed
The Capitalist Roaders Are Still on The Capitalist Road. In
1986, MIM cadre Henry Park published “Postrevolutionary China and the
Soviet NEP” comparing state capitalism in the early days of the Russian
revolution to state capitalism after the coup in China. In 1988, Park
published “The Political Economy of Counterrevolution in China:
1976-88”, which tied all of these subjects together through a Maoist
framework and analyzes the failures of state capitalism in post-Maoist
China.
Pao-Yu Ching’s From Victory to Defeat serves as a more
up-to-date introduction to the topic of the differences between
socialism and capitalism in the last 100 years of Chinese history. It is
written as a sort of FAQ and provides a broad overview, while explaining
the key concepts that allow us to differentiate between the two economic
systems. As such, MIM(Prisons) recommends Pao-Yu Ching’s work as a solid
starting place when exploring this topic. The topic of “What is
socialism?” must be fully grasped by all communists.
It seems that Pao-Yu may disagree with the Maoist class analysis. In
eir introduction ey states, “Today the living conditions of the working
masses in imperialist countries have grown increasingly difficult.”(p.9)
Ey then alludes to rising prices, rising debt and precarious work, none
of which necessarily reflect worsening objective conditions. Without a
recognition that these populations are parasitic on the working classes,
this line leads to the politics of the fascists and social-fascist
“Marxist-Leninists” mentioned above. It is also relevant to the question
of revisionism in the formerly socialist countries who looked to emulate
the lifestyles of Amerikans. Since this point is not taken up in the
rest of the book we will not dwell on it here, but it remains the
biggest problem with this work.
What is Socialism?
Many of our readers and those who are interested in what we have to
say in general are still confused as to what socialism is for the
reasons mentioned above. Ultimately it is defined differently by
different people, and it is used politically rather than scientifically.
Pao-Yu outlines what the most advanced example of socialism looked like
quite nicely in eir short book, so we will just mention some key points
here to help clarify things.
Socializing industry first required that the state took control of
the means of production in the form of factories, supply lines, raw
materials, etc. This is where many stop with their definition of
socialism. Some other key things that Pao-Yu points out is that success
was no longer measured in the surplus produced but rather on
improvements in the production and overall running of the
enterprise.(p.20) This recognizes that some will be more profitable in a
capitalist sense, but that the nation benefits more when all enterprises
are improving, not just the profitable ones. Another key point is that
laborers were guaranteed a job that was paid by the state at a standard
rate.(p.28) This eliminated labor as a commodity that you must sell on
the open market. Commodities are at the heart of capitalism. Socialism
is the the transition away from commodities, starting with the most
important commodity of humyn labor.
The above only applied to a minority of the country, as the vast
majority of China was a peasant population. It is only in recent years
that the peasantry is now less than half the population. It is in the
countryside where the capitalist roaders and the Maoists disagreed the
most. Pao-Yu walks us through the different phases of the transition to
socialism and how the principal contradiction shifted in each phase. Ey
explains the contradiction amongst the countryside, where production was
not owned collectively by the whole population, and the cities where it
was. The disagreement with the capitalist roaders was a disagreement
over the principal contradiction at the time, which they thought was the
advanced social system (of socialism) with the backward productive
forces (of small scale farming by peasants). To resolve this
contradiction the capitalist roaders thought they must accelerate
production, industrialize agriculture, and feed the industrialized
cities with the surplus of that agricultural production. This focus on
production is one of the key defining lines of revisionism.
While Marx taught us that the productive forces are the economic base
that define humyn history and the superstructure, he also said the
contradiction with the relations of production is what leads to
revolutionary transformations of society. As Pao-Yu points out, learning
from Mao Zedong, during these revolutionary periods is when the
relations of production become primary, in order to unleash the
productive forces that have become stagnant under the previous mode of
production.(p.30) In other words peasants living under semi-feudalism in
China pre-liberation were not improving their conditions. They needed to
revolutionize how they related to each other, how they were organized,
specifically the class relations, in order to move towards a new mode of
production (socialism) that could meet their needs much better.
Therefore Mao focused on education, theory, class struggle, culture, the
people, instead of focusing on production, profitability, surplus, and
wage incentives, as the capitalist roaders did. The Maoist path took the
Chinese peasants through a gradual process of increasing
collectivization through communes, which was quickly dismantled after
the coup in 1976.
What is Democracy?
Another question those living in bourgeois democracies often ask is
how you can have democracy with only one party, where people are purged
for having the wrong political line? Pao-Yu makes the point well by
explaining that in established bourgeois democracies you can have many
parties and many candidates, because they all represent the same
class.(p.48) This is the case because these countries are stable in
their mode of production (capitalism). In the transition to a new
economic system the political struggle is between two classes. In the
case of capitalism transitioning to socialism, it is between the
bourgeoisie and the proletariat (and their class allies on each
side).
The bourgeoisie by definition is always competing amongst itself, so
it cannot have one party represent all of their interests, except in
extreme crises when fascism becomes viable. In the United $tates today,
the left-wing of the bourgeoisie are represented by the democrats while
the right-wing flock to the republicans. Even amongst these parties are
different bourgeois factions fighting amongst each other. The
proletariat however is united in it’s class interest, so there will be
no need for multiple proletarian parties. There are many books that
outline the components of socialist democracy where people select their
representatives at each level of administration, where free speech and
criticism are encouraged, where education is universal and free and
where everyone is involved in studying theory and practice to shape the
decisions that affect their day-to-day lives. It does not require having
multiple political parties to choose from as bourgeois democracies do in
their electoral farce.
What is China?
Pao-Yu covered China before, during, and after socialism so that the
reader can better understand the differences. As such the book is a good
introduction to the explanation of why China has not been on the
socialist road since 1976. Ey touches on the loss of the guaranteed job,
with the introduction of temporary workers, the ending of the right to
strike and free expression among the workers, the ability of managers to
start keeping the profits from the enterprises they oversee, the loss of
universal medical care, and the focus on production for other nations,
while importing the pollution of those consumer nations. Ey briefly
documents the struggles of the workers to maintain control of the
enterprises they once owned collectively. China is now a capitalist hell
hole for the majority objectively and it does not matter whether the CPC
has millions of cadre who believe the opposite subjectively.
The Global Economy
One point Pao-Yu makes that we have also stressed as being important,
is the role of the proletarianization of the Chinese masses in saving
global imperialism from crisis. When the imperialist economies were
facing economic crisis in the 1970s, one third of the world’s population
was not available to be exploited by the imperialist system. One of the
laws of capitalism is its need to always expand. When China went
capitalist, it opened up a vast population to exploitation and
super-exploitation for the imperialists. This labor was the source of
value that the imperialist system thrived off of by the mid 1980s until
just recently.
Interestingly, Pao-Yu says that almost 30% of the Chinese population
is petty bourgeoisie, owning (often multiple) investment properties and
traveling around the world.(p.111) In a previous article we explained
that we saw China
as a proletarian country still despite its imperialist activities.
We referred to Bromma’s
research that stated China’s “middle class” was 12-15% of the
population some years prior. It is interesting to hear that the
Chinese petty bourgeoisie has reached the same size in absolute numbers
as the Amerikan one. It would be interesting to compare the wealth of
these two groups, we presume the Amerikans remain wealthier. Of course,
China is still majority proletariat, while Amerika is almost completely
bourgeoisified, so the class interests of these nations overall remain
opposed to one another. But we will rarely hear the proletarian voices
from China until a new proletarian party rises there.
The housing market is one example of how China has emulated the
United $tates. Investing in properties has become an important way for
the new petty bourgeoisie in China to accumulate wealth without working.
Just last week, the Chinese investment firm Evergrande made headlines
when it became public knowledge that they would not be able to pay the
billions of dollars they owe. Evergrande has significant backing from
Amerikan finance capital, as is true for the Chinese economy in general.
Therefore the collapse of the Chinese housing market could have real
ripple effects in the global economy.
The fact that real estate investment firms exist in China, and that
they are defaulting on hundreds of billions of dollars owed, is really
all you need to know to see that the economy is oriented towards profit
and not people. Things like inflation and bubbles and stock markets and
speculation just didn’t exist during the Maoist era. The reintroduction
of these things for the last four decades destroyed the progress in
class struggle in China long ago.
A few weeks ago lots of Black folks were celebrating Juneteenth,
which they claimed was about the banning of slavery in the U.$. Say
what? Apparently none of these folks have read the actual 13th
Amendment, which only banned plantation slavery, while opening up far
more slavery with its Exclusion Section, which basically said “slavery
as punishment for a crime is just peachy.”
…how about you get the May 2021 issue of Prison Legal News
and read the main article, “The Punishment Economy: Winners and Losers
in the Business of Mass Incarceration.”
A fact not mentioned in the article was that businesses (owners) in
many foreign countries are making money “servicing” U.$. prisoner
needs.
Until just a couple of weeks ago, me at 75 years old, with various
health problems, was forced under threat of write-up to work as a
kitchen slave. So I get to read the labels on the products used
there.
Oranges and mixed vegetables from Mexico. Cut carrots from Spain.
Franks (weenies) from Canada. Cucumbers from Mexico. Broccoli from
Mexico. Pineapple from Indonesia. Heat sealed plastic gloves from China.
White plastic “sporks” from Vietnam.
Do you think the owners of these businesses make donations to U.$.
politicians that always vote for more laws, more prisons, and more money
to cops?
Wiawimawo of MIM(Prisons) responds: We share this
writer’s concerns about prisoners being used as a source of exploited
value by capitalists. When Third World countries begin to delink from
the united $tates economically, Amerikans will face serious crisis and
imposing fascism on segments of the u.$. population in the form of
slavery is a likely outcome as we saw fascist Germany do.
However, we think the concern about foreign companies selling cheap
produce to u.$. prisons is misled. In fact, most of the value created in
producing that food in the Third World is stolen from those who make the
food and realized in the First World (see our recent review
of John Smith’s Imperialism in the Twenty-First Century).
Even those Amerikans reaping the profits on these food sales to Amerikan
prisons are not likely backing prison construction. Food is about $2.1
billion of the $182 billion spent on mass incarceration each year in
this country.(1)
But what about this question of prison labor? The persyn above has
written us numerous times to challenge our line on prison labor. In 2018
we did a survey of ULK readers to further research this
subject. And we have extensive articles on the economics
of the U.$. prison system available to those interested. But we are
always keeping an eye out for new info, so let’s look at this Prison
Legal News article.
As it turns out, this article does not offer much information on
prison labor at all, far less than our research does. The article is a
thorough documentation of many ways that companies are making money by
offering services to the government related to prisons and to families
of prisoners; what we might call profiteering or even extortion in the
case of fees charged to families.
1 in 8 U.$. jobs
rely on prisons - Big if True
Daniel Rosen doesn’t cite the source of this one in eight jobs
estimate towards the beginning of eir article. Regular writers for
ULK have long called Amerika a pig nation. Then why does Rosen
turn around and ask, “are we just producing greater corporate profits at
American families’ expense?” It is Amerikan families who are getting
payed labor aristocracy wages to work these 1 in 8 jobs that relies on
this system of punishment. Meanwhile, the majority of people suffering
from the injustice system are members of internal semi-colonies, not
Amerikans. And this is the exact contradiction we try to bring to light
every time we get into this debate.
After citing the exorbitant amount spent on staffing prisons, Rosen
offers a section on how employees are underpaid. In states like
California, prison guards start at salaries that most reading this
newsletter will never see in their lives. To make eir point sound
reasonable, Rosen claims “pay for starting prison guards is usually in
the range of $25,000-$35,000.” This range actually represents the lowest
10% of prison guards in the country, with the median actually being at
$45,000 per year starting salary.(2) Is this underpaid? As regular
readers of our work will already know, employed Amerikans are generally
in the top 10% income earners globally, including those that make
$25,000 per year. An individual living on $45,000 per year is in the top
2%.(3) And as many of our readers know, overtime and hazard pay are a
regular occurrence in that line of work, easily putting annual prison
guard salaries into six figures.
Our writer contacted us about prisoner labor, not prison guard labor.
The reason this is relevant though is that it represents the economics
of those who see prisons as a product of corporate interests. It often
comes hand-in-hand with those who see $50k/year pigs as the oppressed
and exploited opposed to the corporate interests. Even if they’re in the
top 2%, they are still in the bottom 99% that the left wing of white
nationalism sees as allies. This idealism wants to see all people come
together for a common cause, ignoring the different material interests
of different groups in the world today. We focus on prison organizing
because there is a greater consciousness in prisons that these pigs are
part of the imperialist system and that they serve the enemy because
they benefit from that system.
I Pay Your Salary, Buddy
Rosen starts off his article with the message that U.$. taxpayers are
paying $80 billion per year to lock people up. While there has been an
upsurge of concern about spending on incarceration in the halls of
Congress, why is it that the same “fiscal conservative” voters who don’t
want social services are quick to yell “lock them up” when it comes to
so-called “criminals”? Our explanation is that the system that is trying
to control the rebellious oppressed serves them. It serves them with
some of the highest incomes in the world, from which they pay taxes.
These incomes, and taxes, are superprofits stolen from the international
proletariat.
We know many in the prison movement are not Marxists, and therefore
may not accept the labor theory of value. With such people we are
working from different theoretical models and different terminology. It
is not a coincidence that such people are predominately reformists. We
need to be debating Marx vs. bourgeois economics. Even many
self-described “Marxists” in the imperialist countries think there is an
infinite amount of wealth to go around.
Rosen writes, “Recidivists are the primary ‘product’ of the
punishment economy and the real source of its profits.” It’s true,
unlike the military-industrial complex, there is no real product being
made here, just ancillary services like phone calls and food delivery.
But are recidivists the source of these companies profits? No, the only
source of profits is surplus value from surplus labor time. And as we’ll
reiterate here, that is coming from the Third World proletariat.
The Endless Road to
Reformism
Of course, most of the concerns about mass incarceration that Rosen
mentions in this article are ones we share. One that we’ve been
discussing lately is how for-profit communication services are replacing
in-persyn visits and mail under the guise of reducing drugs. Yet the drugs
magically keep getting into prisons, and now prisoners
communications are being digitized for easier monitoring and censorship,
while valuable resources and family connections are being cut off. We’ve
also helped expose the issue of a second-class system for migrants, the
vast majority who haven’t even committed any anti-people crimes, being
stuck in poorly
run, privately-owned prisons on behalf of Immigration Customs
Enforcement (ICE).
We just don’t agree with Rosen’s economics and where it leads us
strategically.
We agree with Rosen that there is a whole slush economy around
incarceration, that’s the nature of the United $tates mall economy in
general. And in the case of imprisonment, the result is buying people
off to support it. There’s too much money, corruption and greed in this
system. But this is nothing particular to incarceration, and
incarceration is just a tiny drop in the bucket that is this problem. Do
we want to make this tiny corner of the imperialist economy a little
less gross? Or do we want to end mass incarceration? liberate oppressed
nations from imperialism? end exploitation of the proletariat? We are
aware that a majority of our incarcerated readers might lean more
towards the first option. And while we appreciate our prison reform
allies who stand with us in many campaigns, this newsletter is not a
forum to promote reformism.
Rosen writes “[t]he most important way that mass incarceration fails
prisoners is by all but guaranteeing that they’ll come back.” This is
one of the true crimes of the system. Socialist countries like China
showed the world how prisons could be used to integrate former
oppressors into a new people-focused society. Yet, “corrections” in the
u.$. has always taken a much different form, one of punishment. And this
is why we prioritize our Re-Lease on Life Program for those released
from prison to help comrades continue to reform themselves and integrate
back into society as servants of the people, and avoid getting locked
back up. Our humble program is a precursor to a system that will serve
to rehabilitate the real criminals on this continent in a socialist
future.
This country not only institutionalizes disparities between the
oppressed nations and Amerikans in the united $tates, it is a tool of
genocide in how it affects the productive and reproductive years of a
vast segment of oppressed nation men. These problems beg the solution of
liberation and independence.
Rosen closes eir article with a number of examples of progress in
reforming the ills ey discusses. We agree these are progressive things,
and yet they do not address the problem. Which is why you won’t see
these campaigns in the pages of ULK. See recent
discussions between USW comrades on how to organize prisoners in a
way that keeps our eyes on the prize. Sometimes our campaigns will
overlap with the reformers. Even then, we must promote the proletarian
line and not succumb to coalition politics.
Imperialism in the Twenty-First Century:
Globalization, Super-Exploitation, and Capitalism’s Final Crisis
by John Smith
Monthly Review Press
2016
[Editor: The author of this review uses “southern countries” to refer to
what we would call the Third World, exploited or neo-colonial countries,
and “northern countries” to refer to the imperialist, First World,
exploiter countries.]
The dominant trend in capitalism for the last forty or so years has
been the relocation of production from northern to southern countries,
where the vast majority of the global industrial workforce lives. It’s
impossible to ignore the offshore origin of most of the commodities we
interact with in the U.S. every day, and equally impossible to ignore
the wretched conditions and dramatically lower wages that most of these
southern workers deal with. What this means for the present structure
and future of the global economy is less clear, and that’s where this
book comes in.
There’s a lot in this book I won’t talk about that was nonetheless
very interesting – Smith’s discussion of GDP and productivity
measurements, his history of Marxist thinking on imperialism, and his
in-depth discussion of the production of a wide range of specific
commodities.(1) I’ll just focus on his main contribution, the value
theory of imperialism, in which he incorporates and expands on Marx’s
discussion of surplus value and Lenin’s century-old understanding of
imperialism.
Surplus in Marx’s Capital
Smith’s value theory of imperialism begins with value, which is the
amount of labor required to produce a given commodity. A capitalist
producing t-shirts wants to churn out the largest amount of them in a
working day, at the highest possible intensity of work, and with the
latest technology. Out of the sale of the t-shirts he buys equipment,
raw materials, and pays wages. These wages are the monetary expression
of labor power, or what a worker is paid to show up at a specific time
and place and put their energies and abilities at the disposal of the
capitalist. In return, the worker can use the wage they get to buy a
basket of goods to keep themselves alive til the next day. The amount of
labor that goes into the production of this basket the worker needs can
be called the value of labor-power itself, which under capitalism is a
commodity just like clothing, pickups or rifles. The pile of shirts the
capitalist gets to sell at the end of the day can be sold for more money
than the wages he pays for the labor that produced it. To cut a long
story short, Marx investigates this anomaly and discovers that there is
a part of the day where workers produce enough commodities to pay for
their wages, and a part of the day where the labor they expend creates
commodities that just make the capitalist money. The labor that happens
in this second part of the day is surplus labor, and the value of the
commodities produced at this time is surplus value. This magically free
labor is the beating heart of capitalism, and its pursuit and
distribution are the core of all capitalist economic phenomena.
Marx discussed two main ways that capitalists in the 19th century
would attempt to grab more surplus value.(2) The first he called
‘absolute surplus value,’ and it consists of extending the working day
by either making workers work harder for the time they’re at work, or
making them work for longer at the same or similar wages. The second
path to more surplus is making the value of labor power (or the amount
of labor it takes to create enough goods for a worker to survive) less.
Marx called this second form ‘relative surplus value’.
Smith takes this basic account and expands it to an era Marx didn’t
live to see and couldn’t have predicted – the transformation of the
labor-capital relationship into a relationship mostly between northern
capital and southern labor.(3)
North-South
relations in Lenin’s Imperialism
Lenin’s book Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism
describes a world divided into oppressor and oppressed nations, the
competition of monopolies, and the trends inherent in capitalist
development of this era that lead to ever more destructive bouts of
violence. The need for more surplus and more profits drives capitalist
firms beyond the confines of their home market, to seize and exploit
foreign ones. Competition gives way to centralization and large
monopolies, and the increasing integration of these monopolistic
interests into the state makes war over colonies and their resources
more and more likely. At home, the super-profits obtained in the
colonies create a labor aristocracy, the size and influence of which has
been debated basically for the entire hundred years since Lenin’s book
first appeared.
Smith identifies a weakness in Lenin’s work, mainly that he doesn’t
discuss or use value as a concept to explain imperialism.(4) The thing
Smith attempts, after several chapters of setting up the data on the
existence and persistence of wage differentials and trade relationships
between northern firms and southern labor, is a synthesis and update of
Marx and Lenin’s contributions.
Synthesis
Smith’s point is that the outsourcing of production has allowed
capitalist firms to conduct what he calls ‘labor arbitrage,’ or buying
labor power where it is cheap and selling the commodities produced where
they can be sold dear. Thanks to innovations in shipping and
communications technology, firms can seek out the cheapest labor and the
most favorable environmental and labor laws (ideally, they want no
environmental or labor laws) to churn out the most surplus value
possible. This has driven the wage down below the value of labor power –
workers in many countries are not paid enough to survive and have to
make a living through wage-labor in capitalist factories plus something
else, like subsistence farming or stealing. This is an extreme form of
the relative surplus value extraction method that Marx discussed, or
what has also been called superexploitation.
Additionally, the relationship between companies like Foxconn (which
actually makes the iPhone) and companies like Apple (who first create a
design that breaks in three years, then contract the production out and
stamp a logo on it for 300% markup), or ‘arms-length outsourcing’(5),
hides the exploitation and transfer of value from one country to another
behind an apparently innocent market transaction. The vast majority of
the profits, taxes and tariffs from offshored production end up not in
the country where the commodity was produced, but in the country where
the final seller of the commodity is headquartered. This is how Germany,
a country that cannot produce coffee, makes dramatically more from its
re-export than any country where it is actually grown.(6) Marx hints
that this phenomenon, called ‘value capture,’ could exist theoretically,
but Smith demonstrates that it is at the core of relationships between
countries in today’s economy. There is also a lengthy discussion of
‘value chains’ or sequential input-output relationships conducted
between firms that leads to the final commodity. A Zambian copper mine
sells to a wire factory, which sells to a company that makes circuit
boards, which sells to a car company who uses the circuit board to run
an automatic transmission in a hundred thousand dollar pickup. The
conditions of work and the selling price dramatically swell along the
chain, to the point where the worker watching a robot bolt the circuit
board into place makes more in an hour than the copper miner made in a
month. But all labor really is equal. It’s not like swinging a pickaxe
is an entirely different movement in Zambia or America. And it’s not
like the people doing the swinging are any different either.
The Political Economy of
Coffee
Smith provides a lot of concrete examples of how these exploitative
relations between nations lead to permanent conditions of
underdevelopment in southern countries, and vast profits in northern
ones. Maybe the most stark of these examples is his discussion of coffee
from the early part of the book. Coffee is only grown in southern
countries, and it is almost exclusively processed in northern countries,
where the markups can exceed four hundred percent. Wages paid in the
coffee-processing sector, taxes from this business and tariffs on
imports, all contribute to the northern economy in question (Germany,
perversely for a country that can never grow coffee except in a
greenhouse, is the biggest exporter of processed coffee) and rely on
southern countries furnishing the raw material at a reliably low price,
a price that ends up being a tiny fraction of the cost of the final
product. In this case it’s clear not only how unequal the exchange is,
but also how the entire chain of production in the northern country
relies on the exploitation of other workers. Another writer on this
subject, Zak Cope, estimates that the total transfer owing to this
process of hyper-exploitation, markup and re-export, across all
commodities, amounts to sixteen percent of GDP in northern countries
every year.
What makes these conditions permanent is the persistently low price
of the export for the country where the coffee is grown, which will not
allow it to develop or move up the ladder to more capital-intensive
forms of production that might be safer on the global market. An
additional factor is politics, and the careful policing of the ability
of southern countries to raise wages, enforce their own labor laws, hold
northern firms to account when they commit crimes(7), and raise the
price of their exports. In the case of Rwanda (a major coffee producer)
in the early 90s, the political destabilization and genocide that
occurred in the country was partially the result of the collapse of an
international coffee-exporting agreement that attempted to set a (low)
floor on the price of the commodity and provide some stability and
guaranteed income for countries who rely on its export. Northern
countries oppose any agreement that would make their inputs cost more,
or make their value-chains dependent on cheap labor any more expensive.
They can be more or less effective at ensuring this, in cooperation with
the comprador bourgeoisie. A particularly galling example of this, from
the textile sector, unfolded in Haiti in 2009 over the raising of the
minimum wage of 31 cents an hour, which president Rene Preval eventually
backed away from, after opposition from the U.S. Embassy and local
factory owners.(8)
Whose fight, and who’s
fighting?
What Smith doesn’t do is discuss the immediate political consequences
of all this for us. On the last page of the book he says “together with
their sisters and brothers in the imperialist countries, [southern]
workers have the capacity, the mission and the destiny to dig a grave in
which to bury capitalism.”(9) It’s a little too convenient, and maybe in
the future he can discuss the history of this elusive internationalism.
Whether workers in northern countries fight actively or consciously for
this super-exploitation to continue, whether and to what exact extent
different groups of workers in northern countries benefit from this
arrangement of production, whether workers of the world can unite and
what they could accomplish if they could, are all questions Smith
doesn’t answer. MIM would argue that workers in northern countries
clearly benefit from imperialism, and seek those benefits in an alliance
(an alliance that might have some rough spots now and then) with the
bourgeoisie of their own countries, and are thus not a mass base for a
revolutionary movement but instead a labor aristocracy. Changes to all
of these relationships – between northern and southern countries, and
between workers and their bosses, north and south – will drive changes
in the political economy John Smith’s book goes a long way towards
helping us understand.
Notes: 1. pp. 13-34 2. p. 237 3. p. 12 4.
pp. 225-230 5. p. 68 6. p. 31 7. It always helps when the
law in northern countries maintains a fictitious barrier between a
northern firm relying on exploitation and those they exploit. A recent
extreme example is the Supreme Court’s ruling that the slave labor of
children used in harvesting product for Nestle under conditions the
company controlled wasn’t technically the company’s fault. See:
https://www.cnbc.com/2021/06/17/supreme-court-rules-in-favor-of-nestle-in-child-slavery-case.html
8. Dan
Coughlin and Kim Ives, 1 June 2011, WikiLeaks Haiti: Let Them Live on $3
a Day, The Nation. 9. p. 315
At this moment Cuba is entering into a new phase in their struggle
which unveils a reality unfavorable to socialist construction. Yet we
should keep in mind that Cuba’s fate remains unsealed. History shows
that the Cuban people are up to the task of fighting for socialism as
they continue to inspire others around the world. They have enormous
amounts of creative and practical experience. Here we examine some of
the positions in the popular debate around Cuba, as well as the true
source of its successes and failures.
Privatization and Pandemic
The current protests in Cuba are the result of growing privatization
of sectors in multiple industries. This has been a gradual trend, but in
February of 2021 it took on new heights. Tourism in particular, as a
private industry, is Cuba’s largest revenue generator making over $3.3
billion for its people in 2018. With the ease
of relations under President Obama there was unfortunately even more
of a rise in privatization and large growth in tourism. Labour Minister
Marta Elena Feito said the list of authorized activities in the private
sector had most recently expanded from 127 to more than 2,000. Some of
these include barbershops, restaurants, taxi services, domicile and
hotel rentals, small shops and cafes. Most of these private sector jobs,
which are primarily in major cities such as Havana, are oriented towards
the tourist industry.
The last report showed that 600,000 people, around 13% of the
workforce, joined the private sector when the opportunity arose.
COVID-19 brought problems as the borders were closed to non-residents in
order to prevent the pandemic’s spread. About 16,000 private workers
asked for their licenses to be suspended, according to the Labor
Ministry, which temporarily exempted them from taxes. Shortly after, the
amount increased to 119,000, which was roughly 19 percent of the private
workforce. This measure allowed for a small section of the private work
force to be protected during the pandemic, however other sections,
mostly in tourism, were catastrophically hit.
U.S. Economic Warfare
The labor ministry stated that the decline began before COVID-19 as a
result of Trump’s new additions to the embargo on Cuba. In December of
2020, Cuban tourism had fallen by 16.5% due to U.S. sanctions that
imposed restrictions on travel to Cuba, money transfers, and trade
between Cuba and other nations. The U.S. Office of Foreign Assets
Control in 2020 stated the following in regards to the more recent
additions, “OFAC is removing the authorization for banking institutions
subject to U.S. jurisdiction to process certain funds transfers
originating and terminating outside the United States, commonly known
as”U-turn” transactions. Banking institutions subject to U.S.
jurisdiction will be authorized to reject such transactions, but may no
longer process them.” The rules also block money sent to Cuban
government affiliates, and decreased the limit but still allow for
remittances to most families in Cuba.
On 19 October 1960, the U.S. embargo was implemented as policy to
undermine the revolutionary government as a response to its
nationalization of industries and dealings with countries led by
communist parties. Over the coming years tension only increased and the
embargo would continually be adjusted to prevent growth of the Cuban
economy. As of now the sanctions vary with over 231 entities and
subentities like ministries, holding companies, hotels, etc.; meaning
the U.S. is trying to control Cuba’s economy. These provisions also
extend to international companies like the various shipping companies in
2019 which were sanctioned by the U.S. government for participating in
oil trade between Venezuela and Cuba. This was during the same period
that the U.S. was accusing Venezuelan President Nicolas Maduro of
falsifying the election results that left Juan Guaido to bite the dust.
Allegations which later were proven to be false yet nevertheless caused
dire consequences for millions.
Economic terrorism continues to be perpetrated by the U.S. against
Cuba to prohibit other nations and companies from participating in trade
deals. Some ways the U.S. does this is by denying licenses or deals with
U.S.-based companies or other nations that have the audacity to ignore
the U.S. embargo on Cuba. Year after year the U.N. votes in favor of an
end to the embargo with only two nations (the U.S. and Israel) voting in
favor of continuing the embargo.
In 2021 former U.S. Secretary of State Mike Pompeo designated Cuba
once again as a state sponsor of international terrorism in another
futile attempt to further isolate Cuba from potential trading partners.
This designation carries with it the implication that any business or
state which does business with Cuba participates in sponsoring
terrorism. As a result the U.S. will then implement sanctions on those
businesses or states or at the very least deny them vital business
opportunities that they need to sustain a functional economy in a
U.S.-dominated global market. It follows from this that the private
sectors in Cuba who were not prepared for the pandemic, were already
affected by the ongoing trade embargo for about 60 years, with Trump’s
administration amping up attempts to suffocate Cuba’s resilient
economy.
Cuban Protests
Dwarfed by Uprisings in U.S.
When the protests erupted in Cuba this month, the U.S. wasted no time
in opportunistically pushing their agenda. Meanwhile, expatriated Cuban
terrorists living in the U.S. sent videos over social media promoting
the destruction of public property owned by the Cuban people, looting,
assault on peoples security forces etc. These videos, not surprisingly,
never found their way into mainstream reports but were exposed by Cuban
media. Díaz-Canel even made a point to say that there are
revolutionaries who have been misguided by false reports forged by
subversive reactionaries, and people with legitimate demands for an end
to the embargo and reform of failed policies. This made clear that these
demonstrators were not the target of criticism but genuinely concerned,
although in some cases misguided, citizens.
In reality only a small capitalist minority from certain private
sectors affected by the embargo and COVID-19 have taken to the streets
to promote their interests; interests that are antagonistic to that of
the Cuban people. President Díaz-Canel proceeded to visit the
demonstrations himself and speak with people. On live TV Díaz-Canel
called revolutionaries to take to the street and oppose the
reactionaries and to stay in the streets as long as necessary in order
to defend the revolution. It was correctly stated by Díaz-Canel that the
reactionaries with violent intent are of a specific small group who
align with U.S. interests. More specifically from his mouth he stated
that, “They want to change a system, or a regime they call it, to impose
what type of government and what type of regime in Cuba? The
privatization of public services. The kind that gives more possibility
to the rich minority and not the majority.”
Counter protests proceeded to take place where a greater part of
Cuba’s 11 million people came out to demonstrate their support for the
revolution and continuance of socialist construction. With such a small
minority of protestors being for regime change and only a few dozen
arrests we have to ask ourselves why there is such a controversy? It is
only explainable by the private interests and imperialist U.S. who
wishes to finally deal a deadly blow to Cuba. After decades of failed
CIA assassinations, a failed U.S. invasion, and a failed Embargo, the
U.S. government is reiterating its fledgling commitment to undermine the
people of Cuba.
All the while the Amerikans fail to see the irony that in 2020 the
protests in the U.S. were estimated to have between 15 and 26 million
participants with over 14,000 arrests documented as related to the
protests and a number of deaths associated. These numbers are not even
all encompassing in the true magnitude of arrest and torture by the U.S.
government on its own citizens. These protests put forward demands
guaranteed by the Cuban constitution. Article’s 16, 18, 19, 41, 42, 43,
44 of the Cuban constitution reveal rights and guarantees afforded to
Cubans that in the U.S. don’t even exist or are up for debate. A
civil war was needed to end slavery only to have it replaced by Jim Crow
segregation in this country. Without a doubt a quick look at the
Cuban constitution in comparison with the U.S. constitution, one would
begin to question the true ethics of the U.S. and why Cuba is portrayed
the way it is.
Cuba has made greater advancements than the U.S. in many fields. It
achieved a higher literacy rate, lower infant mortality rate, a lung
cancer vaccine as well as a COVID-19 vaccine independently developed
with a 92% success rate. All this despite the embargo and war crimes of
the U.S. The U.S. in their sad attempt to condemn Cuba’s Communist Party
declares the people of Cuba to be subjugated, unable to protest, or have
free speech. As can clearly be seen, the president of Cuba not only
respects the constitutional right to protest and have free speech, but
invited millions to take to the streets to do so.
The Will of the People in
Cuba
In 2018 a new draft of the Cuban constitution removed reference to
communism. This first draft was met with wide-scale protests
and a popular demand that reinstated communism as the goal. In 2019 the
new Cuban constitution reaffirmed the popular will. Time after time the
U.S. is embarrassed by Cuba’s revolutionary people. Which is presumably
why the U.S., who routinely overthrows democracies, assassinates world
leaders, or suffocates nations with sanctions, takes special interest in
torturing Cuba. It is not without effect either, as many Cubans feel
this pressure and suffer untold losses in this cruel escapade waged by
the United States.
Mind you, Cuba is not without mistake. The continued privatization of
industries and reliance on tourism is a massive failure on the part of
the Cuban government. Failures to foster the full creative potential of
the Cuban masses by putting politics in command has led the Cuban
government to become a bureaucratic mess. With a large population of
revolutionary masses eager to promote the ideals of socialism and forge
ahead on their path of self-determination, it is sad to see the Cuban
state fail to remove the fetters on the Cuban people that restrict their
ability to take control of power for themselves. This is a result of
internal contradictions within the Cuban state.
Over the past few decades the gradual decline of peoples’ power has
been witnessed. Today’s events are a result of the pandemic and U.S.
embargo. However, the principal issue is not from without Cuba and it
certainly is not from the Cuban people. It is in the Cuban state and
their failure to remain vigilant against growing opposition forces
within the state itself. Forces that undermine the peoples’ will. Forces
that cause unnecessary retreats and failures in planning. With all due
respect, these are serious errors that must be rectified by campaigns
led by the revolutionary Cuban people. Only the Cuban people can
determine their destiny.
So our appeal to Cuba should be directed towards the revolutionary
masses who represent the socialist majority. We are in solidarity with
you and support you. We will continue to fight to bring to an end the
U.S. embargo and all interventions. The revolutionaries in Cuba who
emulate the ideals as well as principles of socialism with the aim of
building communism are a continued inspiration to the freedom fighters
all around the world.
Díaz-Canel welcomed revolutionaries to the street to participate in
open debate and oppose the reactionaries. This is a step in the correct
direction. So long as those revolutionaries are allowed to progress down
whatever path they find suitable for themselves to sustain their
revolution. So long as they combat the reactionaries as well as the
revisionists. All of this on the terms set forth by the revolutionary
Cuban masses themselves who are truly world renowned heroes of
revolution.
MIM(Prisons) adds:
It is not MIM line that Cuba was ever really on the socialist road. The
Cuban revolution was very clearly one of national liberation from
imperialism. However, Cuba paralleled the Derg in Ethiopia in taking on
“Marxism-Leninism” for geo-political reasons related to using the Soviet
Union as a counter-balance to other imperialist interests. That’s not to
say there weren’t Marxists in their ranks, most popular movements in the
Third World are going to have Marxist influences. But the Marxists had
not consolidated a party around the proletarian line before seizing
power. They did not follow Mao’s example of building United Fronts with
other classes by maintaining proletarian leadership and independence. In
a capitalist-imperialist world, coalition governments invariably lead to
capitalism.
Cuba stood out for many decades as a symbol of resistance to U.$.
imperialism, even after the fall of the Soviet Union. It is also
well-known for directing resources in the interests of the Cuban people
and the people of the world. In our article on Ethiopia we mention that
the Cubans
had their differences with the imperialist Soviet Union, and that
speaks to the path Cuba took independent of the USSR during and after
its existence.
We agree with current President Díaz-Canel that privatization is only
bad for the people. However, nationalization only threatens imperialist
meddling, it does not address the internal class contradictions of a
country. And in the case of Cuba, with the dependence on tourist money
and remittances, the Amerikans have significant and increasing control
over their economy despite nationalization.
In the United $tates state-run firms (like the post office) are often
defined as “socialism.” But Maoists define socialism differently, as an
economy that is guided by the proletarian line, always engaging in class
struggle, pitting the interests of collectivism, humyn needs and humyn
relations above production, efficiency and profit.
As Mowgli writes, the internal contradictions of a capitalist economy
in Cuba cannot ultimately be resolved without a popular movement to
rectify the current leadership and shift to the socialist road. We would
go further in stressing that socialism is class struggle. There is no
policy shift that can bring a country to the socialist road, only the
militant mobilization of the masses concentrated in a communist party
that puts the class struggle at the forefront. Our opposition from
within the empire to the embargo serves to help the Cuban people see
their dreams come true via continued class struggle.
A Texas Prisoner wrote: “Recently on sum conservative
radio show there was a persyn who asserted that amerikkka is a”socialist
country and has been for a long time.” A pupil and i argued about this
because i’m like, amerikkka is the antithesis of socialism, but as i
read your reply this debate re-entered my mind along with the
conservative ploy to confuse the masses with “red baiting,” equating
everything “left” of center as die hard communist/socialist but in
essence what the persyn on the radio program was really saying was that
amerikkka is a social democratic country and has been for a long time. i
still disagree, wat about u? And wat is the difference, if any, between
social democracy and democratic socialism?“
Plastick of MIM(Prisons) responds: For us Maoists,
social-democracy is the tendency where as opposed to Marxism or
communism, they seek to apply a welfare state such as the likes of
Sweden while capitalism is the main basis. Democratic socialism is a
revisionist Marxist trend where they claim that socialism is the goal
where the workers run the world, we must do it through non-violent and
reformist means. The confusion could go deeper for some newer comrades
as the Bolsheviks of the Russian revolution called themselves as
upholders of Social-Democracy. To Lenin and Stalin, social-democracy
meant socialism and modern democracy in a backward semi-feudal
imperialist Russia, not sharing a section of the imperialist pie to the
Russian masses. But the International Communist Movement later abandoned
“social-democracy” to those who thought capitalism could be reformed to
serve humyn need.
Social-Democracy’s core characteristic is appeasing the masses
through reforms and better short-term conditions while preserving
bourgeois dictatorship. In an imperialist country, social-democracy can
mean better wages and living standards for the labor aristocracy who
might be growing tired of inflation. In the Third World there are just
as much social-democratic movements as the comprador-bourgeoisie seeks
to quell the majority proletarian populations of their respective
countries. Ironically, despite its efforts to preserve Liberal bourgeois
democracy, social-democracy oftentimes paves the way for fascism,
particularly in the exploiter countries. In Germany, social-democracy
crushed the revolutionary movement both by appeasing to the workers
through oppressor nation chauvinism and militaristically ridding the
revolutionary leadership. When economic crisis in Germany deepened to
where social-democracy couldn’t govern its masses the way it did before,
fascism arose to put forth law and order.
People often talk about social-democratic countries being the middle
ground combination between capitalism and socialism: Amerika is a
capitalist country, China is a communist country, and Sweden is a
social-democratic country. This is a metaphysical view of what a
country’s political economic system is – qualitatively all of these
countries are run by a bourgeois dictatorship. Out of these countries,
Sweden is the most famous for its social-democratic way of governing.
There is a similar social-democratic movement in the U.$. that wishes to
follow those countries lead, but to say a country is social-democratic
is misunderstanding what social-democracy is: it is a trend that arises
out of the labor aristocracy/petty-bourgeoisie during times of hardship.
If social-democracy fails, the coin will flip to reveal the other side
of fascism.
The last two presidential elections demonstrated an increase in
pressure from the labor aristocracy for social democratic policies. All
advanced imperialist countries have social services paid for off the
backs of the Third World proletariat. If we want to split hairs and say
some of these countries are social democracies, we’d say the U.$. is not
currently one because it has extreme privatization, going so far as to
privatize some prisons.
There is zero question that Kansas is using prisoners for cheap labor
and profiting tremendously from multi-year sentencing of first-time drug
offenders like myself.
I “earn” sixty cents per day to perform a skilled labor sewing
position full time. If I refuse to work I will receive a disciplinary
work report resulting in my custody security level to rise.
There is a 30-person crew that works at the Kansas State Fairgrounds
year round. These prisoners also receive 60 cents per day. The
fairground complex could not operate without prison labor.
These jobs are not maintaining KDOC prisons. They are part of the
state prison economy, for the profit of the state.
Also, this prison takes 50% of the earnings of all private industry
job income prisoners earn. At the private industry jobs, prisoners make
minimum wage ($7.25/hour). Incarcerating probation-eligible offenders to
minimum-custody facilities to work is proof that in Kansas, exploiting
prison labor is a motivating force for mass incarceration.
In almost every other state I would not have been sentenced to prison
for possession of medical cannabis.
I understand the point of the article was to look at medium and
long-term goals. As a non-violent, non-victim, first time drug offender
I believe cannabis decriminalization is a goal worth pursuing. Thousands
of people in Kansas have been incarcerated by a corrupt, prison labor
motivated criminal justice system.
Is the author agreeing that non-violent, non-victim, first-time
cannabis offenders should be working for 60 cents a day to assist the
state economy and provide cheap labor for giant factory farms in Kansas?
When I see corrupt judges play in to this state economy, there are no
myths in my first-hand facts. If I am misinterpreting Wiawimawo’s
writing, please clarify what the author intended.
Wiawimawo of MIM(Prisons) responds: First, thanks
for the details on how prison labor works where you are in Kansas. We
regularly publish such reports on our website and use them to keep tabs
on the realities of prison labor over time. You are our on the ground
reporters for everything going on in U.$. koncentration kamps.
One thing you don’t specify is who you are making clothing for at
your job. That is an important factor. Usually people are working on
clothing and sheets and now face masks for other prisoners to use. That
would be work for the prison system, not for profit. Similarly, running
the fairgrounds is for the state. These are parallel to the examples of
fire fighters given in my original article.
None of these jobs are making profits for anyone, which you seem to
have confused. Multiple times you refer to Kansas as profiting from
prisoners. States do not make profits. They have revenue and expenses,
and they can run over budget if they want with expenses being greater
than revenue by issuing bonds. Now the bourgeois definition of profit is
netting more money coming in then you put out in expenditures. But even
bourgeois economists do not use this terminology in regards to states.
As Marxists, we define exploitation as paying workers less than the
value that they produce and then selling the product (or service) to
realize the full value. This is the source of wealth accumulation in
capitalism.
Now to the prisoner sewing clothes for 60 cents a day, it matters
little whether those clothes are to be used for state-issued use or sold
in a store. So i can understand where you’re coming from. But if we want
to explain how the prison system works in this country this becomes an
important distinction. It is not profits for big businesses to
accumulate capital that drives the system. It is a combination of
financial self-interest of the people who work in these institutions,
people who some would have us see as the oppressed proletariat
themselves, and the broader interests of the oppressor nation to control
the oppressed nations in this country. Through this control of the
oppressed nations by Amerikans through criminalization and imprisonment,
they can further gentrify the places oppressed nations reside and create
further economic control for themselves. This is the heart of our
analysis. And it is why we have a very different orientation than the
petty bourgeoisie who is opposed to private prisons for profit and favor
drug decriminalization as discussed in my original article.
“Is the author agreeing that non-violent, non-victim, first-time
cannabis offenders should be working for 60 cents a day to assist the
state economy and provide cheap labor for giant factory farms in
Kansas?”
No, i do not argue that. We argue for more change, not
less. We are not reformists, and we don’t think drug
decriminalization in the United $tates will eliminate national
oppression nor drug addiction. If done well, it could reduce these
problems, and the specific expression of drug problems such as marijuana
consumption. Therefore the reform is progressive, but it does not solve
the problem of national oppression and the criminal drug economy. We
have much better solutions for national oppression and drug addiction,
and they certainly don’t include imprisoning people for victimless
behavior. They do include eliminating profit motives in all aspects of
our lives. In the meantime, we support an international minimum wage
that would apply to prisoners.
A California Prisoner: The Covid
and imperialism article in ULK 72 sparked my interest
because I am already vaccinated and I had to ask myself why I, a
prisoner, was vaccinated before tax payers? The answer was pretty simple
logic. Prison is huge profit for California and the cash cow has been
closed for Covid crisis, the sooner California can reopen the prisons,
they can continue to rake in the profits they make from our
suffering.
Wiawimawo responds: There was a significant effort
in California by lawyers and activists to get prisoners to the top of
the vaccination list. And this is at least part of the explanation as to
why you got vaccinated early. It made sense from a public health
standpoint, but this did not happen across the country because many
Amerikans don’t care about prisoners’ lives.
It is not clear why you argue that profits dried up in prisons during
the shelter-in-place, so i would need more information on that to
respond. But as i explain above, states don’t profit from prisons.
Prisons are a huge financial expense and do not create any economic
value. Prison labor is one way to slightly reduce some of the expenses
in running these prisons.(1)
All that said, i want to address this comrade’s talk about the “tax
payers.” The vaccination campaign across the United $tates is being paid
by the Federal government. The government has now passed a series of
bills in the trillions of dollars to address the fallout from the
pandemic. This is not “tax payer money.” They are just printing money,
or creating money out of thin air to fund these programs. Since the
dollar is the global currency, they can do this with some confidence
that other countries and investors will buy up the bonds to cover the
expense. It’s all funny money that we benefit from here in the United
$tates, even those in prison benefit at times, thanks to our position as
the premier imperialist power.
This is in stark contrast to countries like India and Brazil that are
now being hit hard by the pandemic and the people are being offered
little relief. One reason is that these countries can’t just print $1
trillion worth of their currency without causing massive inflation and
damaging the conditions of the people more.
To the extent that it is “tax payers” who are helping to balance the
budget deficit in the United $tates, we must also be clear where that
money is coming from – the Third World proletariat. The above is just
one demonstration of how value can flow from the periphery to the
imperialist countries. This is reflected in the incomes of all U.$.
citizens, who must give some of those super-profits to the state to keep
the imperialist system running.
So let us not shed a tear for the poor “tax payer” in this country
because California actually made some efforts to vaccinate people in a
way that made sense in terms of promoting public health. There is no
shortage of vaccines in the United $tates. In fact, we have far more
than we need, while other countries have not even begun vaccinating
their populations yet. If we were really working in the interests of
public health, we would have a more equitable distribution of vaccines
across the globe. We’d be prioritizing hotspots, which the United $tates
is. And we’d be sharing the technology needed to make vaccines freely,
releasing the intellectual property that is holding back progress in the
fight against COVID-19. Failure to do so means that the virus will
continue to evolve and likely continue to be a problem.
A New York prisoner: In response to ULK 72
(2021) article “Help
Fund MIM(Prisons), Donate Now!”, I would like to offer a suggestion
outside of charity from donations which seems to be a necessary form of
income for the production, maintenance & shipment of ULK’s.
What if MIM took some of its donations and invested them in the stock
market? I know that seems pro-capitalist, but as the old adage goes you
gotta fight “fire with fire.” Making a few short-term trades could
possibly boost revenue for expenses (solely), and make donations a
welcomed part of production but not so necessary. This would keep MIM’s
line of no foreseeable future in capitalism by not becoming long-term
investors in the stock market, but instead looking for quick returns in
order to fund revolutionary work (i.e. short selling, which is basically
betting against the U.S. market, which is still in some ways inherently
communist behavior). I am enclosing an articled dated 11 January 2021,
“Jay-Z Fund to Help Minority-owned Cannabis Businesses.” What do you
think about this venture? I don’t really believe lumpen have the luxury
of investing in non-essential production/consumption as cannabis right
now, when they don’t even have land to cultivate on. But financial
freedom is nonetheless a form of independence… so keep on keeping on
Jay-Z!
Wiawimawo responds: First, we agree with using the
oppressors’ tools against them, and have no moral qualms about the stock
market. Proletarian morality means we do what will most benefit the
liberation of the exploited and oppressed. Whether it is a wise
investment is another question. Conventional wisdom is that it is a good
long-term bet, but unpredictable in the short-term. As for shorting,
well hedge fund Melvin Capital Management lost 53% in January in its
infamous shorting of Gamestop.(2) They lost about $6 billion on that
bet. That’s what the stock market is, gambling.
Now cannabis businesses, that might be a more sound investment. As
the article points out, and as i discussed in my article on Tulsi
Gabbard mentioned above, the legalization of weed has been a bonanza for
white petty bourgeois interests trying to get small businesses up and
running before the large corporations dominate the market. New Afrikans
are under-represented in business ownership overall at just 10%, but in
the states listed that number was 3-6% for cannabis businesses.(3)
Jay-Z, and New York State are correctly recognizing this gap and trying
to do something to not let it happen in New York.
What do we think about this? More equal opportunity for the petty
bourgeoisie just reinforces imperialism. When it was illegal, oppressed
people selling weed were targeted by the state and potential allies to
the anti-imperialist movement. People running successful weed businesses
aren’t likely to be our allies, regardless of their skin color.
The weed game is in a major transition. It is still in a semi-legal
state, where the Feds could crack down on you (and they have). Getting
access to loans and bank accounts can be difficult as a result. One
group that is proving successful as early pioneers in the trade are
former law enforcement. They are less likely to be targeted by the state
than a former felon, and they have clout to deal with the pressures from
extortion rackets and the lumpen organizations they are competing with.
Therefore as revolutionaries, the weed business might be risky.
You suggest that we need to invest in stocks to free us from our
reliance on donations. On the contrary, we are trying to become more
reliant on donations so that our cadre don’t have to worry so much about
funding everything ourselves, which we do by working or investing or
whatever. Maybe some of us are investing in the stock market to fund
this work, but that is not a reliable source of income. We want to be
going strong when the market collapses again. And that is why we want to
be reliant on the financial support of the masses. Only by relying on
the people is our future secure.
As i said above, legalization of weed will not eliminate national
oppression in the forms of cop killings and disproportionate
imprisonment rates. It will make pacifying substances more readily
available to the masses. And for better or for worse it will undercut
the underground economy in favor of public tax revenue. And that is what
this is about of course, it is providing tax revenue to maintain
government funding at the local and state levels.
Until the import of weed is legalized by the feds, this shift of
production to the United $tates will be undercutting a source of profits
in the drug trade – the Third World farmer. Historically the farmers who
grow and process weed are the ones being exploited in Third World
countries. As production shifts to the First World, wages will have to
increase to exploiter-level wages, with the possible exception of using
migrant labor from the Third World. This means the profits must come
from other sectors in the Third World instead, to pay the farmers,
marketers, sales people and accountants in the First World running the
new weed economy, as well as the state taxes. If the exploited weed
farmers are eliminated, then the profits must now be squeezed from the
banana farmers or copper miners, and all the other exploited workers of
the Third World. This puts more pressure on the already dangerously low
international rate of profit.
Finally, we agree with your point about land. Without land there is
no power. National liberation means liberating the territory of the
oppressed. Owning land as individuals is not it. Oppressed nations must
control land as independent nations, and be able to defend that land.
This is a central task of the New Democratic movement.
[MIM(Prisons) are not lawyers. The legal information provided by
jailhouse lawyers in ULK is verified to the best of our
ability. This particular issue seems like a winnable battle based on the
information provided, but winning will take more effort by comrades in
Texas.]
Prisoners in Texas are having the money from their stimulus checks
taken by the state to pay fees and restitutions. Section 272(d)(2) of
the Consolidated Appropriations Act provides that the second round of
stimulus checks ‘shall not be transferable or assignable, at law or in
equity, and no applicable payment shall be subject to execution, levy,
attachment, garnishment, or other legal process, or the operation of any
bankruptcy or insolvency law.’ This means that this round of stimulus
checks may not be garnished to cover overdue debts by federal or state
prisons.(1)
The stimulus checks have the same protections as the United States
Veteran Affairs Administration whom sends millions of checks across the
country to incarcerated former military service men and women whom only
get 10% of such checks.
People held by the Texas Department of Criminal Justice - Correction
Institutions Division(TDCJ-CID) are having their stimulus checks stolen
from their inmate trust funds accounts due to debts owed in the
following categories, with the percent of each deposit they will deduct
for each category:
current/prior TDCJ sentences (old or new, no amount specified)
I have written a complaint – a TDCJ Step One Offender Grievance Form
No. 2021020837 that said the direction would come form the IRS as to
whether those stimulus checks would be exempt from collection. The
response was that this “action was out of the control of the unit, no
action warranted.”
Thereafter, I appealed that response in another complaint Step Two
Offender Grievance Form. I wrote the agents in charge at the IRS
Department of the Treasury in Austin, TX but never received any
response.
Scholl v. Mnuchin, et al. No.4:20-cv-05309-PJH ND Cal.; Appeal
Docket No. 20-16915 9th Circuit Court of Appeals ruled in favor of
prisoners getting stimulus checks while incarcerated. The checks in
question should not be confused with the most recent $1400 checks under
current Presdient Joseph Biden. It was the $1200 and $600 checks under
President Donald Trump that were ruled on. These checks should be issued
whether one is incarcerated or not because everybody is affected by this
global crisis.
According to The Intercept the TDCJ was ironically the only
state they spoke to that claimed it was not garnishing stimulus checks
to its prisoners. Many, if not all, states have seemingly been breaking
the law in doing so.(2)
There is a solution to safe-guard some form of protection to those
stimulus checks or other funds.
MIM(Prisons) adds: The author provided names of some
companies that used to provide banking services for prisoners. These
companies all seem to have closed down. We leave this note here as a
suggestion for possible solutions to storing your stimulus money if you
can find a similar service that is trusted.
Also note, that according to caresactprisoncase.org, if you have not
filed the tax forms for the stimulus checks by 15 April 2021 you may not
be able to receive them. At the same time, the official word has gone
back and forth on how all this works.
Some comrades have written in to say they are boycotting the stimulus
checks. While we agree that these stimulus checks are a means of buying
off the population in U.$. borders with wealth stolen from the Third
World, as individuals we can still do good things with this money. Like
how we view investing in the stock market, we do not take a moralistic
view of this money and encourage comrades to get the funds they are
legally due and put them to good use in projects serving the people and
building independent institutions of the oppressed.
The following is a response to some topics of debate within the
article “Maoist
Third Worldism: Responding to Criticism from a Reader” by Mazur of
the blog Struggle Sessions. “Maoist” projects in the United
States have put forth a number of lines in recent years as worthy of
dividing over. In our mind, there is none more important than the class
structure of this country. And if anyone wants to attempt a follow up to
Mazur’s effort, we request they respond to Imperialism
and its Class Structure in 1997 by MC5, rather than some ideas in
your head about what MIM Thought is.
Value and Price
Struggle Sessions asserts that the proponents of unequal
exchange between imperialism and the oppressed nations (i.e.: finished
goods and export commodities are unbalanced in such a way that the
countries whose wealth is being extracted are given a raw deal) couch
their views in part on a belief that the price of a given commodity is
set as equal across different countries. To that allegation we reply: in
what ‘Third Worldist’ publication has this been written? To my knowledge
MIM has not claimed this, nor was this asserted by the earlier
contributor. Cite your sources. Do not attempt to employ a selective
choice of academics as a stand-in with an eye towards deceiving your
online readership by purposefully distorting matters to the benefit of
your dogmatic conception of economic affairs and reality. That is why it
is easy for you to tear down your chosen academic-as-foil such as in
your statement that:
Amin would later adopt this to equalize price levels so that a given
use value costs the same in U.S. as it does in Guatemala. Before getting
into this this is just not true anyways…
You perceive yourself as rather clever, don’t you. We wonder into
what other topics of discussion you have inserted such imperious
analysis and judgments which have also resorted to similar rhetorical
deceptions and sleights-of-hand. Also, if our stance on unequal exchange
was really a “less sophisticated version” as you claim, wouldn’t you
just stick to picking apart that easier prey instead? So we see again
that you, Mazur, have run into problems, problems concerning deceit and
faulty logic in equal measure.
You are at least correct on one thing, and that is your statement
that your academic could not stand the test of Marxism. So let’s drop
any other “version that is worth using” and stick with Marxian
economics. And by Marxian economics, we do not refer merely to its
classical conception (it is worth noting that Marx claimed even he was
not a Marxist, alluding to the fact that Marxism is a living science,
ever changing and developing new insights, not static and impervious to
advances in economic complexity over time); we also refer to its
continuity within a Leninist framework in the era of imperialism,
super-exploitation and the labor aristocracy, which Lenin gave clarity
to and which MIM Thought has further expanded upon through materialist
analysis.
You allege that in our analysis we deliberately ignore the labor
theory of value. So, we will begin with Marx:
What, then, is the value of laboring power? Like that of
every other commodity, its value is determined by the quantity of labor
necessary to produce it. (1)
‘Value’ in its final form must correspond to the labor power embodied
in a given commodity. Yet properly gauging this has become more complex
under imperialism. The main way we have typically measured it is through
its price, its exchange value. This follows what is termed the law of
value, but, when commodities and the labor embodied in them (what is
termed ‘dead labor’) are transferred from the developing peripheries to
an imperialist nation via multinational corporations, the connection of
value to its price is distorted to the point where the product (your
banana) is finally placed in the produce section at an American
supermarket, so much super-profits have accrued from not paying the
Guatemalan workers the value of their labor that upon its sale there is
enough excess profit for the United Fruit Co. to in turn bless its
American management and warehouse employees with more than the
value of their labor, in effect purchasing their allegiance to where
they no longer have just their ‘chains’ to lose. They have become
invested in the continuation of super-exploitation of the Guatemalan
proletariat as have many additional Americans in their role as
consumers, fresh off the job in your glorified manufacturing sector, who
purchase the produce (yes, despite paying over its market value in
Guatemala “and regular distribution and retail costs, the speculative
costs of the money market, etc.”) and, being entitled to similar wage
privileges, can also afford to have their money manager include shares
of United Fruit in their investment portfolio, if they so choose. As for
our plantation worker: “In Guatemala, where the minimum wage is roughly
$11 a day” and workers “struggle to bring home even $220 a month” (2),
they may not have the luxury of being able to afford the very product of
their own toil without first considering whether it will cut into other
essential purchases or payments owed, despite it selling for close to
its actual value. The logic behind these processes are so elementary
that all but those who are ‘so intelligent, they are stupid’ cannot fail
to comprehend it. This is on display when you surprisingly acknowledge
that this wealth transfer happens to the extent we describe, yet
simultaneously are unable to understand or remain willfully ignorant of
its far-reaching implications. You state:
“Because of capital export it does indeed follow that the U.S. is a
net importer of commodities and that there is a stratum of monopoly
capitalists who derive their profits solely from interest from their
direct foreign investment that melts down to this strata …”
But, not to be deterred, you say that exploitation happens at the
point of production and the lazy dogmatist in you resurfaces as you go
on to state further:
“… but the U.S. is still the second largest manufacturer in the
world, behind only China. This is something the ‘TWist’ does not want to
recognize, that the class which has nothing to lose but its chains is
concentrated in large numbers in the USA.”
Who is
proletarian? Are they a revolutionary vehicle?
We are glad that we can agree that the proletariat is the class that
has nothing to lose but its chains. But the relevance of manufacturing
statistics we find confusing. Once again, you do not want to recognize
the full extent of this wealth transfer, but this time as it plays out
in the domestic manufacturing sector:
“They can’t compete with China in terms of labor. An American
manufacturing employee makes an average of $26 an hour, while his or her
Chinese counterpart makes only $5 an hour, according to the Reshoring
Institute.”(3)
American manufacturing operations are still dependent on raw
materials and parts with unpaid-for embodied labor within them that is
obtained under a system of super-exploitation and shipped across borders
for Amerikan workers to tinker with. This results in wages that are at
least five times higher and above the value of their labor because there
is enough money being made for the capitalists to both turn a profit and
purchase their allegiance. When you deny the hidden transfer of value
between national economies, perhaps it makes sense to estimate the size
of the proletariat based on GDP numbers as Mazur does above. The United
States being “the second largest manufacturer” only proves that a lot of
value is being realized here, not where that value is coming from.
While, we do not recall anyone ever not recognizing that
some Amerikan workers are employed in the manufacturing sector, the one
thing we do not equate them with is being a part of the proletariat.
Lenin reexamined the meaning of ‘proletarian’ in a more nuanced manner
when he said:
“The Roman proletarian lived at the expense of society. Modern
society lives at the expense of the modern proletarian. Marx
specifically stressed this profound observation of Sismondi. Imperialism
somewhat changes the situation.”(4)
The proletariat can most accurately be described as the social group
that is the revolutionary vehicle. This does not mean that it is
synonymous with the industrial working class for all times and contexts.
Mao understood this when he harnessed the immense latent power of the
Chinese peasantry, who at the time made up around 95% of the population.
They became the revolutionary vehicle while the industrial workers, due
in part to their marginal proportions, assumed more of an auxiliary
role. Would you also embrace the lazy dogmatism of the Trotskyists who
cling to their orthodoxy with a religious fervor and state that, because
the peasantry is not the industrial working class, it cannot be capable
of being the backbone of a revolution? History showed us otherwise,
while you would have been as insistent as Chen Duxiu and got nothing
accomplished. No, Mazur, in this matter you are much like the ‘Marxists’
who see Cuba or China as socialist. How so? Because you identify things
based on their form rather than their substance. You have lost the
ability (if you were ever able) of discerning who is revolutionary and
who is not, who are our friends and who are likely to betray us to
protect their stake in the system. You see occupations instead of
workers economic co-optation within that occupation by way of a
reactionary vested interest in their allegiance to empire and its
spoils. This makes you no different than the ‘Communists’ of yesteryear
who saw workers in hardhats attacking demonstrators protesting U.S.
involvement in Vietnam as objectively revolutionary, or the socialist
parties who supported their nations’ entrance into imperialist world
wars as to the workers’ benefit at the munitions plants:
“Thus, on the outbreak of the imperialist war in 1914 the parties of
the social-traitors in all countries, when they supported the
bourgeoisie of their ‘own’ countries, always and consistently explained
that they were acting in accordance with the will of the working class.
But they forgot that, even if that were true, it must be the task of the
proletarian party in such a state of affairs to come out against the
sentiments of the majority of the workers and, in defiance of them, to
represent the historical interests of the proletariat.”(5)
This is why when you say that our line leads one to the inevitable
conclusion that the working class in the U.S. and other imperialist
countries are the main exploiting class of the people of the world and
that “this would make the task of Communists to divide and discourage
the just rebellion of the masses,” we would concur, save for the whole
bit of rhetorical flourish about it being a ‘just rebellion.’
But you continue harping on that the imperialist working class faces,
in your words:
“… exploitation in many forms, with work speed-ups, greater temporary
contracts, de-skilling, through greater constant capital being
introduced and wage depression.”
Clearly such things applied to even an exploiter working class would
still benefit the capitalists. We do not claim that these workers are
insulated from unfair working conditions despite benefiting from their
relationship with imperialism, as they remain the subordinate partner in
this role. But we do not go so far as to label it ‘exploitation,’
because being ‘exploited’ is a very precise Marxist term. We would like
to make clear that this does not mean that by extension we believe that
no one faces conditions of exploitation within the imperialist centers,
nor do we “contend that there is no proletariat to organize in the
imperialist countries.” The previous ‘TWist’ contributor also did not
claim this. They criticized you for arguing “that the labor aristocracy
is not the majority class in the first world” (emphasis ours).
MIM(Prisons) has this to say:
“Our claims, however, are far from this. Our claim is that the masses
here are a minority force: they are oppressed nation, they are migrants,
they are prisoners, etc. We have been saying this for many years, yet
[our critics] ignore this line and claim that we do not believe that
anyone is oppressed in the First World. We don’t claim that there are no
masses here, we claim that the constantly dying imperialist system needs
to fall in order for proletarianization of the labor aristocracy to
happen.”(6)
We can look to segments of the internal semi-colonies including the
over 500 Indigenous nations on the continent, sectors of the Third World
diaspora including the so-called ‘illegal’ migrant workers residing
within imperialist borders, the revolutionary youth and intellectuals,
and the revolutionized lumpen and prison populations as wellsprings for
our revolutionary mass base in this country. But you would, again,
looking at form rather than substance, likely scoff at this and act like
we are just going to accept and network with these groups uncritically
as we encounter them and not pursue their further proletarianization.
This is not the case. We also express with a higher degree of actual
confidence and certainty that the above-mentioned groups have a greater
interest in seeing the tables turned in this country, and turned
violently, than your bourgeoisified working classes you seek to lose
yourselves in.
And note: it is at this point that, having just detailed
our position clearly and corrected the record, we will formally ask you
to cease claiming that we believe that there are no proletarians or
masses within the imperialist centers to practice the mass line
with. Quote us correctly. Honesty may not come naturally
to you, but those who stumble across this blog page deserve a truthful
and accurate representation of views other than your own. You can only
deceive the masses for so long before they find out and call you on your
bullshit. On a related note, it is amusing (while incorrect) that you
paint proponents of the labor aristocracy-maturation line as “largely
abstentionists from revolutionary practice” when we can observe the
prison ministry of the MIM testing its ideas, struggling with the
imprisoned masses and developing theory through practice. Providing this
leadership and developing new cadre in the prisons while retaining
fidelity to anti-imperialism and the international proletariat is a
verifiable practice of theirs. On the other hand, it remains to be seen
how you and your lazy dogmatist cohorts will translate such fine
rhetoric as “recogniz[ing] the importance of organizing the proletariat
[in the manufacturing sectors] as a vital trench, to defeat
imperialism’s political influence through the labor aristocracy among
the proletariat” into concrete policies and actions.
Role of
Consumption in Determining Our Friends
You are quick to dismiss arguments about Amerikan access to wealth by
saying that as real Marxists we know that exploitation happens at the
point of production,
“We see then that exploitation does not happen at the level of
circulation. It happens at production as will be explained further
below.”
Yet we do not argue that the proletariat is being exploited at the
supermarket. Rather we are saying that surplus value is calculated by
the simple arithmetic of subtracting value received by the worker from
the value added by the worker. Therefore, increasing value received has
the potential of creating a negative value on the right-hand side of
that equation; surplus value can be negative. Of course this can only be
true for a subset of so-called workers or capital would cease to
circulate.
You take another grain of truth from Marx and extrapolate it
inappropriately in your sentence:
“For TWists who distort Marxism, the greater amount of use values a
wage can command=the lesser degree of exploitation of a waged
worker.”
Marx’s model predicts an increase in use values becoming available to
the proletariat, and even becoming part of the value of labor (the basic
cost of survival). An example of this would be that by 2018, 83% of
adults in Third World countries had a cell phone.(7) Banking and other
services are often only available in remote regions via cell phone.
Therefore, having a cell phone in general would not be a good indicator
of the degree of exploitation someone faced in 2018. Whereas in 1990, it
was a good indicator that you were not exploited.
You continue,
“Pure and simple, a temp worker at a plastic shop earning 25,000 in
the USA doesn’t exploit anyone, while a food production small business
owner in Managua who earns less than 25,000 who has employees who earn
less than what he does exploits – exploitation requires a position of
ownership and control over the means of production.”
While 86% of adults in Kenya have a cell phone (less than half of
those have smart phones), the average consumption of the poorest 20% of
Amerikans is about 10 times that of the average Kenyan.(8) What economic
logic would Struggle Sessions use to justify enjoying use
values an order of magnitude greater than those in the Third World,
while maintaining that both groups are exploited proletarians with
nothing to lose but their chains? Here you argue that an Amerikan making
more money than a Nicaraguan has more revolutionary potential. What
happened to “nothing to lose but their chains”?
Another metric provided at the website above is the number of Big
Mac’s a McDonald’s worker can buy with one hour of wages in 2007. An
Amerikan working at McDonald’s at that time could buy 6 times as many
Big Macs as an Indian working the same job.(8) Will Struggle
Sessions argue that the Amerikan is more productive flipping
burgers? Not to mention the fact that most Amerikans are now engaged in
service work like this where the possibility for great increases in
productivity don’t even exist as they do in manufacturing.
From there we must ask, what systems of militarism, war, borders and
financial manipulations must be maintained to keep that differential
between the Amerikan McDonald’s worker and the Indian one? And how does
Struggle Sessions propose we can organize these Amerikan
McDonald’s workers to oppose militarism, war, borders and international
finance manipulating the economies of the Third World?
Pray tell, comrade, how are you going to combat the siren
song of the labor aristocracy in their workplaces, especially when you
fail to even properly recognize who is and isn’t a part of the labor
aristocracy? And we ask, are you going to offer less
opportunities to fight for ill-gotten spoils of imperialism? No, that
won’t do it, no. So not only are you going to 1) hop into the ‘trench’
of worker privilege, valiantly protecting and further fattening the
bloated hourly earnings of production workers, their pension plans and
paid-vacation leave; but 2) you are going to attempt to convince them
that they should want to overthrow the government and corporations which
supply their cushy material existence; following that up by 3) asking
them to be on board with a future reduction in pay and standard
of living to pursue the objective of an equal global distribution of
wealth and reparations to the Global South; and 4) all the while being
supportive of a proposal for a demilitarized, open border with Mexico so
that the working classes of all nations can pursue better employment
opportunities?
Mazur, we can’t even say that we wish you luck (and certainly not on
the first point); just that it’ll be the workers themselves, not their
employers or security, picking you up and throwing you out of the
factory floor and onto your ass. But go ahead and falsify our thesis and
you will effectively accomplish what no amount of keyboard clattering on
your part can do at present. That is essentially what it comes down to.
Show us. Moreover, do so without inadvertently activating
social-fascism.
Applying Marxism to Our
Conditions
In the 100-odd years since the first successful revolution leading to
a dictatorship of the proletariat, none have occurred in an imperialist
country with the industrial working classes as the revolutionary
vehicle. You acknowledge we are right in pointing this out. Yet you
still cannot comprehend the full gravity of the labor aristocracy
maturation-line to know that the reasons that you cite for this failure
(fascism, revisionism) are intrinsically tied up with a failure on the
part of Communist organizations to determine the true extent of the rot
and subsequently to cease catering to the labor aristocracy’s demands
altogether. The problem lies in part with the fact that you believe (as
if it were still the second decade of the last century, not the current
one) that:
“The reality is such a condition for labor aristocracy is rooted
fundamentally in the opportunist political leadership of sections of
organized labor, courting favor with U.S. imperialism in competition on
a world scale. It was never defined, by Lenin, Mao or any other past
revolutionary movement from among the oppressed nations and proletariat,
as a strata that encapsulated the entirety of the working class (white
or otherwise) of the ‘First World.’”
Lazy dogmatism rears its head once more when you go referencing the
classics without taking into account the particular dynamics of our ever
deeper progression into the imperialist era and our unique geographic
location within it. Chairman Gonzalo had something to say about people
doing just that while expounding on the need to better understand Maoism
and struggle for its supremacy. In our quest to promote a better
understanding of the full implications of the labor aristocracy
maturation-line and the necessity to struggle for that line over the
ossified views of our erring Maoist fellow travelers, we will quote him
at length (we feel that, if nothing else gets their attention perhaps
quoting him will be the spark necessary to get the ‘Principally
Maoists’ to correct their thinking on the matter):
“In order to better understand Maoism and the necessity to struggle
for it, let us remember Lenin. He taught us that as the revolution
advanced in the East it expressed specific conditions that, while they
did not negate principles or laws, were new situations that Marxism
could not ignore, upon the risk of putting the revolution in danger of
defeat. Notwithstanding the uproar against what is new by pedantic and
bookish intellectuals, who are stuffed with liberalism and false
Marxism, the only just and correct thing to do is to apply Marxism
to the concrete conditions and to solve the new situations and problems
that every revolution necessarily faces. In the face of the
horrified and pharisaic ‘defenses of the ideology, the class, and of the
people’ that revisionists, opportunists, and renegades proclaim, or the
furious attacks against Marxism by brutalized academicians and hacks of
the old order who are debased by the rotten bourgeois ideology and
blindly defend the old society on which they are parasites. Lenin also
said clearly that the revolution in the East would present new and great
surprises to the greater amazement of the worshipers of following only
the well-trodden paths who are incapable of seeing the new; and, as we
all know, he trusted the Eastern comrades to resolve the problems that
Marxism had not yet resolved.”(9) (emphasis ours)
We would add to Gonzalo’s statement that Lenin would have also
trusted the imperialist nation comrades to resolve the problems that
Marxism-Leninism had only begun to address and solve, and to not
mechanically parrot their words on the scope and potential solutions to
problems which in their time were but saplings compared to the broader
trunks and deeper roots which we must now contend with, axe in hand. The
labor aristocracy maturation-line, flowing from Lenin’s
analysis of the split in the working class movement in the early 20th
century with its antecedents in Marx and Engels’ analysis of the English
working class in the 19th century, contends that this split has only
continued and with minimal interruption for the past 100 years in the
imperialist centers, absorbing whole sectors of the working classes,
bribed now in a thousand more ways than before. It was impossible for
Marx, Engels and Lenin to examine and address these issues as well as we
can today, because they were a relatively new development at the time.
We, however, now have the extensive benefit of hindsight, history and
statistics not available then. Yet Lenin did direct our attention to its
creeping progression:
“The longer bourgeois democracy has prevailed in a country, the more
complete and well established it is, the more successful have the
bourgeoisie of that country been in getting into those leading positions
people who are reared in bourgeois democracy, saturated in its attitudes
and prejudice, and very frequently bribed by it, whether directly or
indirectly.”(10)
Mao also spoke on this subject:
“In the various nations of the West there is a great obstacle to
carrying through any revolution and construction movement, i.e., the
poisons of the bourgeoisie are so powerful that they have penetrated
each and every corner. While our bourgeoisie has had, after all, only
three generations, those of England and France have had a 250-300 year
history of development, and their ideology and modus operandi
have influenced all aspects and strata of their societies. Thus the
English working class follows the Labour Party, not the Communist
Party.”(11)
Because of this, Mao went on to disagree with Lenin:
“Lenin says, ‘the transition from capitalist to socialism will be
more difficult for a country the more backward it is.’ This would seem
incorrect today.”(12)
We can no longer point to just ‘the opportunist political leadership
of sections of organized labor’ and call them the whole of the labor
aristocracy. They now represent a class of workers who have become
bourgeois in outlook and have only grown exponentially over time. At
what point do you realize and accept that the imperialist nation
industrial working classes and service sectors are no longer a viable
revolutionary vehicle for Maoism, and that we must focus our organizing
in areas separate from these? At what point do things finally begin to
click into place for you, or are you allowing your pride and dogmatic
rote-learning to blind you to the reality which screams for recognition?
If for whatever reason hearing this message from us in particular is
just too much to stomach, then we recommend the book Labor
Aristocracy: Mass Base of Social Democracy by H.W. Edwards for more
detailed analysis. We encourage everyone with an inquiring mind to not
just take our word for it – examine our references and arrive at the
necessary conclusions on this important subject matter. Do not allow
idealism or lazy dogmatism to cloud your judgment any longer to the
futility of throwing yourself against the wall of the labor aristocracy
in your organizing efforts.
There are two final matters we would like to address. The first is
that it is said we have come by our views through and subsequent traffic
in “petty-bourgeois empiricism-posing-as-analysis,” to which we
reply:
“The lazy dogmatists actually see no real role for science in
agitations. In response to Mao’s proof that line is decisive, they
accept at face value the revisionist slander that calls Mao idealist. By
downplaying science, they pave the way for fascism, which consciously
relies on mysticism for victory in people’s hearts. They imagine that
being good Maoists means being idealist, not practitioners of the
science of Marxism-Leninism-Maoism.”(13)
By criticizing our use of statistics, percentages and numbers, you
are by extension leveling your criticism at Lenin:
“Lenin used many more such statistics, including Tsarist statistics
and criticized those who would not make much use of them.”(14)
Our critics don’t like it when we use basic addition and subtraction
to show that their math doesn’t add up.(15) We must remind our readers
of this line:
“For TWists who distort Marxism, the greater amount of use values a
wage can command=the lesser degree of exploitation of a waged
worker.”
Does that mean you believe the inverse? As First Worldists you
believe that material wealth can increase infinitely without
disqualifying one from being exploited? Must we bring up the old NFL
player example and ask if they have nothing to lose but their chains?
And to pivot to our final topic, Colin Kaepernick was protesting the
murder of young Black men in the streets by the state, not wages or
working conditions. Same reason cities burned across the country last
year, and the same reason they’ve burned almost every other time in the
last 60 years.
Nations
We find your agnosticism on the national question problematic, “In
regards to the white nation, we [Struggle Sessions] have not
taken a formal position on this.” First we are in the era of
imperialism, which is defined by the contradiction between nations. To
not be able to address the national question in one’s own country is to
fail to address the whole of modern political economy. Second, the
question of first importance is who are our friends, and who are our
enemies. To not have a line on the nature of the euro-Amerikan nation,
while having a very well worked out line on military strategy in the
United $tates (a line we know is dear to the hearts of Struggle
Sessions authors), is a dangerous example of putting the cart
before the horse.
To address the question as you raise it, we will begin by saying that
U.S. imperialism is a multinational project in two respects. The first
pertains specifically to the makeup of the Euro-Amerikan oppressor
nation, and the second in the national-patriotic sense with the
inclusion of token elements of the New Afrikan and Latin@ bourgeoisie in
leadership positions both in business and government and the
participation of their respective labor aristocracies in the plunder of
the Global South. But our focus is in addressing the seeming paradox of
the Euro-Amerikan Nation, and whether it is myth or fact. You state
that:
“In this case they are lumping a bunch of languages, cultures,
regions and psychologies into one nation. For instance the psychological
makeup of Jews, Slavs, Irish and Anglo Americans are not the same, and
their languages are often different, too.”
The Euro-Amerikan Nation (or ‘white’ nation in more simplified terms)
has historically assumed the role of dominant oppressing force since the
founding of the United States. Being ‘white’ in America is not only so
much a matter of genealogy and physiognomy as it is one of hierarchy,
both in terms of class and nation. We agree that these people were
something else before they were ‘white’ or Euro-Amerikan – Corsican,
Welsh, Jewish, German etc. Yet through a common historical bond rooted
in violence, rape and looting of labor and land, began a process of
washing the disparate tribes white, a belief in being ‘white,’ becoming
a unified, melded nation in the patriotic and national sense. In the
United States, the separate Irish, Anglo, Polish, etc. immigrant
nationalities of old are now mostly forgotten ‘dead nations,’ with
forgotten mother tongues, blended beyond recall save in surname or
remnant cultural practice seldom exercised in day-to-day existence. They
have transformed themselves over the generations into a single unit
sharing a common culture, language (English), economy (within the
borders of the U.S. excluding most other nations) and territorial
cohesion (again, much of North America). Your denial of this could only
be justified by some racial theory of bloodline.
For you to say that ‘there is no common economy, there is no common
language, there is no geographic territory, and so on’ is an ahistorical
delusion that serves no purpose whatsoever. By denying this, it would
seem that by extension you would also deny the same ‘nation’ status for
the ‘Black’ or New Afrikan Nation, and furthermore any right to their
own self-determination because ‘at best’ you see several nations that,
through participation in the brutal receiving end of the
settler project in the past, were able to achieve uneven status and
integration into ‘blackness.’ (Mazur links to a now official paper by
Struggle Sessions that addresses the intersection of so-called
“race” and class in relation to New Afrika. For now, we will present MIM
Theory 7 as a counter to that piece.)
The Great Migration of Black sharecroppers to the industrial north
and west in the early to mid 20th century dispersed the population of
the Black Belt south throughout the modern colonial borders of the
United States. Nonetheless, New Afrikans constitute a nation as a result
of the historical (forced) melding of different cultures, languages and
psychologies into a new and unique shared culture, language and segments
of territory. It is our hope to one day see the will of the New Afrikan
Nation expressed in a plebiscite on self-determination. Perhaps Mazur
& Co. will be on the right side of history when this occurs.
One final note, we are in agreement with the statement that:
“‘Privilege’ itself, as well as the absence of national oppression,
does not in any way actually prevent those with a relative ‘privilege’
from facing oppression and exploitation as well.”
The white youth, intellectuals and revolutionized white lumpen and
prisoners have an interest in revolution as traitors to their class and
nation. We do not overextend our analysis to exclude these potential
allies in our struggle.
Notes: 1. Karl Marx, “Labouring Power,” Value, Price and
Profit, Martino Fine Books, 2017 p. 39. 2. Lauren Villagran, “A
Desperate Quest for American Dream Denied,” USA Today, December
23, 2020. 3. Michael Braga, “Manufacturers Facing Hurdles in Return
to US,” USA Today, December 22, 2020. It should be noted that
back in 2018, hourly earnings for production workers were pegged at
$22.71 according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of
Labor. Thus a steady increase has occurred in 2 years’ time rather than
a trend towards wage suppression as our labor-aristocratic Maoists
allege. 4. V.I. Lenin, “Imperialism and the Split in Socialism,”
Lenin’s Struggle for a Revolutionary International: Documents
1907-1916, John Riddell, ed. New York: Monad Press, 1984
p. 497. 5. Jane Degras, ed. The Communist International:
1919-1943 Documents, London: Frank Cass & Co., 1971 Vol. 1,
p. 129 (hereafter Degras) 6. MIM (Prisons), “A Falsifiable Thesis,”
Who’s Got Something to Prove, JMP?, August 2020.
www.prisoncensorship.info 7.
Laura
Silver, 5 February 2019, Smartphone Ownership Is Growing Rapidly Around
the World, but Not Always Equally, Pew Research Center. 8.
https://www.justfacts.com/income_wealth_poverty#international 9.
Communist Party of Peru, “Introduction”, Fundamental
Documents. 10. Degras, Vol. 1, p. 119. 11. Mao Tsetung,
A Critique of Soviet Economics New York: Monthly Review Press,
1977 p. 50. 12. Ibid. 13. MIM Theory Number 10, “Lessons From
the Comintern: Continuities in Method and Theory, Changes in Theory and
Conditions”, Coming to Grips with the Labor Aristocracy, 1996.
p. 22. View PDF at www.prisoncensorship.info 14. Ibid., p. 42. See
Lenin’s “Statistics and Sociology,” Collected Works, Vol. 23.
Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1964. p. 271. For Mao talking about
dogmatist lazybones, see Mao Tse-Tung, “On Contradiction,” Four
Essays on Philosophy. Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1968
p. 37. 15. MC5, 1997, Imperialism
and its Class Structure in 1997, part C.5..
Responses
MIM(Prisons) submitted this response to Struggle Sessions.
While no response has been received yet, we cannot expect from them in
days, what took us many months. However, we have already received some
astute responses from others that we are including here.
ADDENDUM
1: A comment on ‘Mazur’s’ understanding of unequal exchange
by marlax1g
The theory of unequal exchange of Samir Amin is one thing, the theory
of Arghiri Emmanuel is another. I do not know if MIM ever commented on
the distinction between the two theories (perhaps for political purposes
given the overwhelming First Worldist hysteria surrounding it), but the
theory of unequal exchange ‘in the strict sense’ as based on global wage
differentials is what MIM (and also Cope’s 2012 book) have always made
reference to; ‘Imperialism and its Class Structure in 1997’ makes
explicit reference to wage differentials in Section
A Chapter 5-6
and Section
C Chapter 5. This theory does not depend upon either differing
organic compositions or differing productivities within the same branch
of trade. And Emmanuel’s criticism of the doctrine of comparative
advantage does not depend upon a criticism of the quantity theory of
money, as he implies in quite literally one of the first paragraphs of
the Introduction. The reference to declining terms of trade in Emmanuel
has absolutely nothing to do with the distinction between primary and
non-primary commodities (explicitly contrary to the Prebisch–Singer
hypothesis), but rather with the wages in the two sectors. Let us note
one more error on the part of Mazur before we get around to explaining
where the error arises.
“If there are the same prices and the wages in the U.S. are higher,
and capital goods costs the same, then the cost price of any given
commodity would be higher in the U.S. This means (since the price of the
finished commodity is the same) that the rate of profit would be lower
in the U.S., so no transfer would even take place.”
Let’s start from the basics. Ricardo’s theory of comparative costs
represents a “special” case where the labor theory of value is
invalidated. The labor theory does not govern prices at an international
level, Ricardo states, because profits cannot equalize. Profits may
equalize within nations because capital is mobile, but it cannot
equalize between nations where capital is immobile as such immobility
results in specialization and therewith the governing of comparative as
opposed to absolute cost. Wages do not enter into Ricardo’s equation
because he operated under the assumption that wages tended towards the
subsistence level because of the Malthusian law of population. (In other
words, Ricardo takes equal wages as a given.)
Marx overthrew the Malthusian “iron law of wages” and this fact is
the starting point for Emmanuel. What Emmanuel emphasizes is a world
where capital is mobile, and therefore profits do indeed tend towards an
equality, but where the Marxian law of exogenous wages rules. Why does
this matter? Because labor is not mobile, and because wages in the First
World are in fact higher without being subject to the discipline of
equalization, wages are the only ‘independent variable’ governing global
prices of production. It is no argument against Emmanuel to claim that
he abandons the labor theory of value, because in the real world market
prices fluctuate around not values but rather prices of production.
Perhaps Mazur missed the publication of Volume Three of Capital, but
Emmanuel had not. Hence “factor rewards” (namely wages) are not given by
prices, but rather prices are given by “factor rewards” (in neoclassical
parlance). Emmanuel therefore inverts the logic of
Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson: prices do not determine wages, but rather
wages prices. This is Emmanuel avec Marx.
The products of industries employing workers at low wages, therefore,
have relatively low prices, and those which employ workers at high wages
have relatively high prices. This is precisely the point of Emmanuel’s
argument — because we are dealing with different commodities being
exchanged. Critics of Emmanuel imagine that they are intelligent in
coming to the profound conclusion that high wages translate into a lower
rate of surplus-value and therefore profit. Emmanuel does not deny this;
he instead shows that with an equalizing profit rate the surplus-value
of the Third World is transferred to the First World because products of
low prices are exchanged for products of high prices. It’s really quite
that simple. And to repeat ourselves for the tenth time, the prices are
high and low because of differing wages. To believe otherwise is nothing
more than marginalism. Emmanuel’s argument is not, in fact, that unequal
exchange is preferable to lower wages in the First World from the
viewpoint of the capitalist; it is only that the lack of wage
equalization partially compensates the drop in the rate of profit.
No child, us Third Worldists do not argue that super-profits
originate in circulation (a libel of Bettelheim), but rather in the
super-exploitation of the Third World proletariat. If they were not
super-exploited, if the rate of surplus-value was not in fact higher,
there would not have been enough surplus-value to transfer and either
First World wages or capitalism itself would have had to collapse.
Mazur writes that:
“Because the organic composition of capital has allowed much more
surplus value to actually be generated, we see then that the rate of
exploitation is often higher in spite of wage increases.”
Imagine such crass physicalism coming from an avowed defender of the
labor theory. Capital with a higher organic composition does not allow
“more surplus-value to actually be generated”. It quite literally
implies less variable capital (relative to its size) and therefore less
surplus-value because constant capital does not contribute an iota of
surplus-value. Mazur wants us to believe that because capital-intensity
is usually higher in the First World, this axiomatically makes First
World workers more “productive” of surplus-value. First Worldists have
never proven labor intensity is higher in the First World, which is what
this claim necessitates demonstrating. We have already seen that this
does not put a dent into Emmanuel’s theory, and Emmanuel explicitly (and
consequently) asserts that, e.g., First World primary producers
(Australian coal, Canadian timber, etc.) still benefit from unequal
exchange. But this is of course a mirage, and as soon as the parasitism
of the labor aristocracy confronts the “Marxist” defender of the labor
theory of value, they turn into John Bates Clark and want us to believe
that wages are governed by labor’s marginal productivity.
I could continue, and I would like to defend Sakai from the virulence
he has been subjected to, but I will leave that to someone perhaps more
competent than myself.
ADDENDUM 2: On Appalachia
loop-3: Given that MIM(Prisons) has no materialist
analysis of the region, and certainly no experience organizing within
it, it is unclear why you now incorrectly say that
“Poor whites in Appalachia… have an interest in revolution as
traitors to their class and nation. We do not overextend our analysis to
exclude these potential allies in our struggle.”
This is a striking political regression. The actual Maoist
Internationalist Movement had a far more correct position on this.
According to MC5,
“Often times we Marxists are told that we should go organize the
Appalachian poor for their economic demands. Duncan gives us some
up-to-date evidence on why that is a silly idea. Between 1980 and 1990,
Blackwell county shrunk in population by 12%. That is the real social
movement of Appalachia. Yes, there is a shortage of jobs, so people
move. That is why there is no class solidarity or class consciousness
that arises in Appalachia, no matter how many Marxists bang their heads
on the wall there. To the extent that Marxists do influence or awaken
anyone, they simply move or succeed in their middle-class ambitions. We
do not need Marxism for that and hence we find the subject matter of
Duncan’s book boring. It is about how to integrate people into
middle-class life. There is no other possibility when poverty is only in
isolated pockets and not a generalized economic condition within a
country’s borders…
“Even if Appalachia had closed borders, it would only then be
equivalent to some of the poorer European countries. At $15,321, central
Appalachia’s median income would still be more than 10 times higher than
that of the median for the international proletariat. Between 1980 and
1990 meanwhile, Gray Mountain’s income literally doubled.
“Both the Mississippi Delta and central Appalachia are shrinking in
population. Already in 1980, the two infamously poor regions combined
had only a population of 1.8 million in a country of 226.5 million with
open borders internally. In other words, they are less than one percent
of the population and it was ridiculous to expect any class formation
there. By 1990, the two regions combined shrunk to less than 1.7
million, or less than the number of people in prison today.
“The trillions in super-profits sucked out of the Third World make it
possible for whole countries to be rich like the United $tates. Although
inequalities continue to exist within the United $tates, they are not
nearly as central or as important to Marxists as those on a global
scale.”
In addition, MIM Theory 1, in the article “Pittston Strike Shows
Depth of White Working Class Alliance,” favorably quotes from this
section of J. Sakai’s Settlers on this issue:
“Despite the 60 years of repeated radical organizing drives [in
Appalachia] there has been, in fact, zero revolutionary progress among
the mining communities. Despite the history of bloody union battles,
class consciousness has never moved beyond an embryonic form, at best.
There is no indigenous [here, Sakai is referring to regional whites]
revolutionary activity - none - or traditions. Loyalty to U.S.
imperialism and hatred of the colonial peoples is very intense. We can
see a derailment of the connection between simple exploitation and class
consciousness…
“This points out the fact that what is poverty-stricken about
settlers is their culture.
“The Euro-Amerikan coal miners are just concentrating on ‘getting
theirs’ while it lasts. In the settler tradition it’s ‘every man for
himself’. They have no class goals or even community goals, just private
goals involving private income and private consumerism. Meanwhile, the
local N&W land manager says that they do have future plans for
Appalachia: ‘We don’t intend to walk off and leave this land to the
Indians’. Of that we can be certain.”
MIM(Prisons) respond: We thank loop-3 for pointing
this out and include eir well-cited argument here. And we have removed
the clause “poor whites in Appalachia” from that sentence as it was
misleading as if the class interests of that population somehow make
them more likely allies than anyone else in the white nation. We must be
cautious and clear when trying to organize Amerikans around their own
interests. While virtually everyone has some interests opposed to
imperialism, and anyone can end up a victim of the system, white
Amerikans must go against their class and nation (and gender) interests
to ally with the international proletariat and the communist project, as
S. Xanastas correctly pointed out in that paragraph.
White youth have more gender interest in revolution and are less
bought into their class and nation. White lumpen arguably have some
class interest different than other Amerikans. What is more clear is
that white lumpen will more often take an interest in revolutionary
politics when they are surrounded by oppressed nations in prison or part
of multi-national lumpen organizations. As for the intellectuals
mentioned, they do not have different interests so much as a different
view of the world. So it is in these groups that we see the greatest
percentage of exceptions to the rule – those who are willing to go
against their own class and nation interests and side against U.$.
imperialism.
A California prisoner asks: “What are MIM’s thoughts
on”Antifa” and what and who are Antifa? Any information you can provide
will be helpful, thank you.”
MIM(Prisons) responds: Antifa stands for anti-fascist,
and it derives from movements in Europe that have a deeper history that
we won’t attempt to address here. It’s primary symbol is a black flag
and a red flag, symbolizing the unity of anarchists and communists of
all stripes in unity against the fascists. “Antifa” is a generic term in
the United $tates. There is no central organization, only local
collectives. Anti-Racist Action is probably the most active formal group
that is akin to Antifa in the United $tates.
The Antifa strategy is one of confronting various stripes of racists,
white supremacists, fascists, etc. in the streets and in their
communities. When such organizations make a public stand, especially
when they organize marches, Antifa will try to make sure there are more
counter-demonstrators and will attempt to shut down their actions. The
long-time Antifa activists often focus on researching these groups,
tracking down their members, doxing them and exposing them.
MIM has never been involved in this type of organizing. Strategically
we think it focuses on a fringe element rather than the real enemy –
imperialism. Imperialism is murdering people in the streets, locking
them away and torturing them, bombing countries, starving whole
populations and polluting the world. Fighting nazis in the street does
not contribute to ending imperialism at this time. Nor does campaigning
against Trump.
That said, if fascism gains traction in this country, then we need to
assess when to shift our strategy away from imperialism as the primary
enemy and towards the fascists. At that time we will certainly be
allying with and relying on some of the knowledge of those that have
been following these groups closely for years.
Why is Antifa in the News?
So why is this comrade asking us about Antifa now? Probably because
President Trump threatened to declare it a terrorist organization, among
other rants against them over the years. So why is Trump talking about
Antifa? As the self-proclaimed enemies of all things racist and fascist,
the various elements of the alt-right/dissident right/third positionists
and racists in online forums have accepted Antifa as their enemy (more
on these groups below). Donald Trump rose to popularity in part by
following the media outlets associated with these movements and echoing
their talking points, one of which is the danger and threat that Antifa
poses. Many of these groups use videos of street fights and
confrontations between their members and Antifa as recruitment material.
(Antifa as such has little to do with the recent uprisings in the United
$tates against police murders, though certainly many who work in Antifa
groups participated in the protests as well. Trump’s statement falsely
implied that Antifa was behind these uprisings.)
The President of the United $tates stated that Antifa is terrorism.
In other words, he said opposing fascism should be illegal in the United
$tates. Quite a bold statement. One that thankfully received strong
rebuke from the majority of the state apparatus at the time. In response
to that statement by Trump, MIM(Prisons) joined the calls in the streets
that “we are all Antifa.”
Is Fascism on the Rise Due
to Crisis?
Since the 2016 presidential campaign we have published a series of
articles addressing the question of whether fascism is here, or on its
way. An article we published in November 2016, arguing that the crisis
that would trigger fascism just wasn’t there yet, ended with, “That
being said, based on Trump’s statements and actions, if Amerikan
capitalism was truly threatened by the oppressed internal nations,
Trump’s open chauvinism would easily transition to far heavier fascist
tendencies.”(1) Now in 2020 we had the broadest display of street
actions, largely by oppressed nations, seen in most of our lifetimes, if
ever in this country. And we have a downward trend in the economy due to
declining rates of profit and exacerbated by a global pandemic. So we
are in a crisis, and as the threat to Amerikan capitalism becomes more
and more real, so does the threat of fascism.
Theoretically, fascism is always on its way in the advanced stages of
imperialism. This is because of the inherent contradictions within
capitalism that make it harder and harder to extract a profit from the
circulation of capital. Without profit, the economy stops under
capitalism. That is why the COVID-19 shut downs have been so disastrous.
Under socialism, we could cut back production and shelter in place
without threatening the future of the economy.
Denying this reality, one of the ideological leaders of the alt-right
called on the Trump administration to just shut down the economy for a
period and restart again like a long weekend. But capital must
circulate, when it does not things begin to collapse like a house of
cards. The amount of value being circulated in the realm of finance
capital just got a shot of another few trillion dollars by the COVID-19
stimulus bills. This money was created by the Fed from thin air. Most
countries would face a decrease in currency value and increase in
consumer prices if they did this. The U.$. is depending more and more on
international finance capital to come into the country to prop up the
dollar and Amerikan consumerism. But if there is no profit to be had,
that finance capital stops coming. The reason this hasn’t happened
already is that the bourgeoisie is aware that a slowdown in finance
capital circulation will lead to a collapse of the system like a house
of cards. This is when the all out war option of the fascists becomes
the only option.
Parasitism Begets Fascism
Another alt-right ideologue, has recently put out a video denying
that fascism is capitalism in decay. Eir thesis is that if there was a
crisis in profitability of capital that the system would have to go back
to some kind of feudal system and greatly reduce production to restore
profits. Since fascism in Germany increased worker incomes and overall
production, ey argues this proves fascism was not a response to crisis.
This logic sort of makes sense from the revisionist “Marxist”
perspective that anyone employed is exploited and that profits don’t
cross borders.
The MIM answer to why the capitalism in decay thesis is correct is in
parasitism theory. Really, few would deny that Germany’s economic
flourishing came from the literal and brutal robbery of land, resources
and labor (through enslavement) of other peoples. But similar things
occur in all imperialist countries, even if just a bit more “civilized.”
We point this out to show how revisionism calling itself Marxism plays
itself nicely into the ideas of fascism. And it is through the appeals
to a populist class interest of the labor aristocracy that the fascists,
social democrats and revisionist “Marxists” all bolster support for
imperialism, despite their rhetoric against war or whatever.
Another thing all of these forces have in common is labeling things
based on their form rather than their substance. Whether it’s the
“Marxists” who see Xi Jinping as leading a socialist country or the
fascists saying that Mussolini was opposed to the bourgeoisie, they are
putting ideas, words and symbols above substance. They say, “see the
leader said this, therefore ey couldn’t support that.” The capitalists,
as a class, do not care about the words as long as the economic
substructure is still functioning to produce profits. Mussolini (and the
King) ensured that it did as does Xi Jinping today. This is the same
reason why today every multi-national corporation is tripping over each
other to put out statements on and make donations to Black Lives Matter.
Yes, there are ideologues within the bourgeoisie, but the class as a
whole, in order to continue on as a bourgeoisie, must ensure that
profits keep flowing. And if stamping Black Lives Matter all over their
website and social media feeds can assist with that, then call Jeff
Bezos anti-racist.
Oppose Left and Right
White Nationalism
The alt-right is actively extending olive branches to the left wing
of white nationalism, specifically those they refer to as “Bernie Bros.”
Some in the alt-right claim to have 90% agreement with such social
democratic types, specifically in their critiques of capitalism and
calls for populist economic reforms and a state that can deal with a
global pandemic. Our saving grace right now in the United $tates is in
the Black Lives Matter (BLM) movement, as well as the struggles against
ICE detention which has also rallied significant support in recent
years. The outpouring of support for BLM has been surprisingly strong.
Even if the multinationals are just motivated by profits, this is like
nothing we’ve seen in our lifetime. Clearly they have recognized where
the winds are blowing, and it is not towards the racism of the
alt-right.
The fascists argue that they are an alternative to the neoliberal
bourgeois order and the Marxist communist order – hence “third
positionists.” But Dimitrov critiqued this misconception for the
COMINTERN during World War II, stating that “Fascism is the power of
finance capital itself.” The fascists argue that finance capital did not
and does not support fascism in its rise to power. MIM added to
Dimitrov’s thesis in 2005: “It is only the finance-capital dominated
petri dish where fascism grows. Today, the labor aristocracy of ONLY the
imperialist countries is the”main force” of fascism…“(2) So again, all
the groups we mention above, whether”left” or “right” are organizing
this class and activating them towards fascism by telling them they are
the oppressed and they deserve more.
More on Class and Economic
Systems
MIM and the COMINTERN agree on the dialectical nature of class
struggle under capitalism as it relates to the phenomenon of fascism –
that is that capitalism is identified in the contradiction and
interdependence of two economic classes: the proletariat and the
bourgeoisie. In this view, there are two paths, or two economic systems:
capitalism (of the bourgeoisie) or socialism (of the proletariat). Other
classes exist and have their own interests. But they will not shape
history in their image. Our world today is shaped in the image of the
bourgeoisie, and Marx explained why the future lies in the hands of the
proletariat, those who have nothing to lose but their chains.
The petty bourgeoisie (including the First World labor aristocracy)
doesn’t have an image for the world. Their ideology is that of the
bourgeoisie, steeped in individualism. And because of their varying lots
in life, their interests are varied, made up of little groups just
trying to make capitalism work for them. They can be united in the
nation-building project that involves their nation being on top. But
even this will not elicit much sacrifice from this class as a whole
unless conditions are quite dire.
When we talk about the labor aristocracy of the imperialist countries
being the “main force” of fascism, we still agree with Dimitrov that
fascism is the power of finance capital. It is finance capital
that gives these tendencies real power. This truth can be seen when you
investigate the organizations in the fascist realm. The most successful
efforts to unite these petty bourgeois forces and use them towards real
political goals are led and funded by millionaires, with access to
advanced military weaponry and international connections to intelligence
agencies. While there are many small, organic groups that are in this
realm, the ones that pose a real threat really aren’t so organic.
Our comrades in prison can understand this dynamic, where it is quite
common for white nationalist organizations to have “special”
relationships with the pigs, to the point of helping to enforce for the
state. Some of our comrades who have served in the military have also
seen direct coordination between the military and local white
nationalist organizations around perceived threats of oppressed nation
rebellions. It’s the same in prison.
From the proletariat comes the true guerilla, who starts from
nothing, and gains their tools and supplies by taking from the enemy
oppressor. The guerilla does not start out with high-end military
equipment, the guerilla earns it. And even before we get to the military
phase, the true mass character of the communist camp is evident. Even in
the bought off imperialist core, you can see genuine organizers popping
up in all areas, fighting for similar goals, from a real organic desire
for change and humyn progress. In the United $tates this is fed by the
oppressed nations and by the youth and by all justice-seeking
people.
The proletariat of the world must distinguish itself from the
parasitic populism of the First World labor aristocracy. Antifa has not
done this. Antifa is open to militant Liberals because they tend to see
this as a battle over ideas in peoples’ heads and don’t have an honest
class analysis of what is going on.
The alternative that MIM offers is that those of us in the
imperialist countries are criminals that must reform our ways. That the
rest of the world wants us to reform our ways and welcomes us in joining
in building a new world based on internationalism, humynism and
solidarity. The oppressed people of the world must guide us towards true
internationalism and not make excuses for the backwardness of the
bought-off populations. Amerikans still haven’t made right the crimes
they committed against the internal semi-colonies of this land. That is
being discussed in the mainstream today. But we still aren’t discussing
making things right with the majority of the world that we have
exploited, polluted and murdered for the comfortable lives we live here.
This is what we see as pro-active anti-fascism. And it’s not about
taking on some guilty complex for your ancestors, it’s about saying that
you will not pass the exploitation on to your descendants. And this must
be part of the current struggles of the oppressed nations here today, or
else we will just end up with more exploiters with more diverse skin
tones.
Recent United Nations estimates of the economic impacts of the
coronavirus pandemic show that half a billion people, or 8% of the
population, could be pushed into poverty (using World Bank poverty lines
of $1.90 - $3.20 per day). The worst hit areas are projected to be South
Asia and East Asia. This will be the first time global poverty has
increased since 1990 and this could wipe out all the progress made in
reducing poverty in that time.
If the UN’s worst-case projection proves true, it will be a huge blow
to the image of capitalism as a force of progress. In recent years,
capitalists have been using global income statistics to try to disprove
Karl Marx’s theories that the masses are continuously impoverished to
more extremes under the pressures for profits under capitalism. Of
course we have always countered that the bulk of this reduction can be
accounted for by China, whose success is built on the radical land
reform and unleashing of the productive forces during its socialist
period, which ended by 1976. Still, this propaganda point has been hard
to counter in a popularly accepted way.
There is nothing like a crisis to lead people to question
capitalism’s ability to meet peoples’ needs. Yet in the short-term, we
see the interests of the Third World proletariat in some of the
proposals coming from bourgeois internationalists looking to limit the
depths of the coming crisis. A newly proposed plan from Oxfam calls for
$2.5 trillion, “made up of $1 trillion in debt relief, $1 trillion in
additional liquidity mobilized through SDRs [Special Drawing Rights -
which is like grant money from the IMF] and $500bn in aid to support
developing country health systems.” They offer potential impacts of this
plan:
“The immediate cancellation of US$1 trillion worth of developing
country debt payments in 2020. Cancelling Ghana’s external debt payments
in 2020 would enable the government to give a cash grant of $20 dollars
a month to each of the country’s 16 million children, disabled and
elderly people for a period of six months.”
Such life-saving amounts are a fraction of the benefits Amerikans are
already receiving from pandemic-related funding bills. Oxfam has done
the math to back up calls already coming from the
Vatican
for international finance capital to forgive debt to the Third
World. In addition to debt relief, it proposes a $1 trillion fund
(called SDRs above) of international reserves that can be drawn on by
the indebted countries during the pandemic.
The United $tates has passed laws to extend unemployment to
self-employed and informal workers, recognizing the lack of safety net
for those people. Oxfam points out that is only 18% of the population in
rich nations, while for poor nations 90% of the people are informal
workers with no safety net. Oxfam’s report cites the United Nations,
saying that half of jobs in Africa could be lost in the coming months.
But the latest stimulus plan from the United $tates only offered $1.1
billion to address the crisis in poor countries, a mere 0.05 % of the
$2.2 trillion plan.
The Oxfam report hints at an international tax on the most profitable
companies or wealthiest individuals as another form of wealth
redistribution to provide the needed funding. MIM has long stood for a
global maximum income for all of the world’s citizens as a similar form
of limiting wealth accumulation and hoarding.
Madonna somberly referred to COVID-19 as the “great equalizer” from a
luxurious bath in eir mansion. But the Third World proletariat will not
be reporting in on video from a rose petal bath during “stay at home”
orders. Coming into this crisis, 46 countries were spending on average
four times more money on debts than their public health services, and
113 countries had IMF-required austerity plans in place as conditions
for those debts. The people of those countries are starting off far
behind us in the imperialist countries. Health care is already seriously
inadequate, and people were already living on the bare essentials. They
have much less of a cushion than us, despite all our bills and persynal
debts. Madonna is correct that this crisis does affect everyone, both
threatening their health and economic stability, but it is far from
equalizing.
Uniting the globe to fight this pandemic must address the unequal
needs and access of the oppressed nations of the world. Onerous debt
repayments and the economic restructuring requirements that accompany
them, is one of the major causes of the destitution faced by the global
proletariat, reaching its highest point at 191% of those countries GDPs
in 2018. Now is the time to forgive these debts, release control of
economic policies, and grant national self-determination to countries
that have effectively been neo-colonies of the United $tates, and
international finance capital in general, for decades.
Oxfam is calling on the G20 Finance Ministers at their 15 April 2020
meeting and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank which
are meeting 17-19 April 2020, to take on their proposed plan.