MIM(Prisons) is a cell of revolutionaries serving the oppressed masses inside U.$. prisons, guided by the communist ideology of Marxism-Leninism-Maoism.
Under Lock & Key is a news service written by and for prisoners with a focus on what is going on behind bars throughout the United States. Under Lock & Key is available to U.S. prisoners for free through MIM(Prisons)'s Free Political Literature to Prisoners Program, by writing:
MIM(Prisons) PO Box 40799 San Francisco, CA 94140.
This is in reply to the article “An
Ongoing Discussion on Organizing Strategy”, which appeared in
ULK 73. In it, the author labels the following statement as
incorrect and unscientific:
“From an organizers perspective, [struggling for quality-of-life
reforms such as increased phone access] are not battles which we can
effectively push anti-imperialism forward, much less MLM…”
The author cites a failure to apply the materialist dialectic, or the
‘science’ behind scientific socialism, to the situation at hand. When
viewed in isolation and out of its proper context, the conclusion that
they have reached would certainly be a commonsense position to take. And
as they write a little further on:
“How can we then deem that prison struggles aren’t aligned with
anti-imperialism?”
Yet if the quote being critiqued were analyzed in its totality, we
can begin to see more nuance and why such a statement was made in the
first place. So to continue where the partial quote left off:
“…without veering into reformist practices of little tactical or
strategic value. I am aware that arguments of principle can be
mounted to the contrary, but absent a practicable, totalizing
strategy for revolution domestically being put forward by an MLM
organization that is actionable in the here-and-now, we cannot
effectively utilize many of these prison struggles as a proper
springboard to corresponding actions in other areas, actions which do
not translate into long-term pacification which benefits their prison
administration in an objective, cost-to-us, benefit-to-them analysis. If
we cannot muster the resources and external manpower to mount a facility
or state-specific campaign for a tactical reform to push our agenda and
continually imprint firmly in the minds of all incarcerated that we have
their best interests in mind, it may be advisable to abstain from
participation lest credit for the reforms go elsewhere and become
politically-neutered, or, worse yet, the system co-opts the struggle as
its own and touts its successes (ie. The First-Step Act). Otherwise, we
are gaining no more than sporadic traction amongst those we are
attempting to revolutionize, and then only of a transient nature.”
(emphasis added)
As mentioned earlier, there is a nuance to the position I have taken
that is obscured in comrade Triumphant’s approach to mounting an
argument on principle, and that in itself constitutes an incorrect and
unscientific approach to proper discourse. Quoting someone out of
context may buttress a particular argument or agenda, however arguments
begin to lose their strength when quotations are re-situated in their
proper place. You ask, ‘how can we then deem that prison struggles
aren’t aligned with anti-imperialism?’, but who has or where has such a
view been advocated in the first place for this allegation to be made?
As you can see, the position put forth in the original commentary
advocated not an abandonment of revolutionary struggle within prisons
but rather its placement within a more explicitly revolutionary
framework. Refining our approach does not imply an abandonment of all
struggle just to focus on study.
It is agreed that the materialist dialectic can be applied in all
manner of social phenomena, and the Amerikan injustice system and the
struggle between prison staff and the captive population are no
exception. But the real question is, should it be applied in
this particular instance in the manner which the Team One Formation,
K.A.G.E. Universal and others have done thus far – that is, pushing for
minor reforms largely divorced from a wider revolutionary
anti-imperialist agenda resulting in pacification once concessions are
made? I would argue that advocating for these various minor reforms to
address the prison masses immediate needs can be classified as
(presupposing these formations desire revolution or claim communism as
their goal) right opportunist deviations.
Right opportunism is an error in practice that occurs when an
organization attempts to embed itself in the masses and in doing so
gives up a clear revolutionary program in the interest of fighting for
immediate demands. This leads to economism/workerism (or in this case
‘prisonerism’), which is the purview of reformism: solely focusing on
economic demands (economism), or the demands of prisoners.
You write that “quality-of-life reforms are connected to the strategy
of cadre development.” Now can experience be gained in how to train
cadre and organize people while doing this? Sure, but similar things can
be argued about improving one’s marksmanship and related skills acquired
while employed as a cop too. While a rather extreme analogy, what I am
getting at is that productive skills can technically be derived from
incorrect practice. Yet the question for both scenarios remains the
same: Is there a better methodological approach to training cadre?
It is a laudable desire to want to avoid being all ‘study’ and no
struggle, but if ‘struggle’ leads a group to avoiding, obscuring or
watering down their politics in order to attain their demands, then that
is not getting us any closer to our desired results. As MIM(Prisons)
notes:
“We can also say that only focusing on the reformist campaigns,
without the larger goals, is not going to change anything in regards to
ending oppression and injustice.”
It is encouraging to see that in consequence of previous organizing
experience comrade Triumphant has pledged to focus on “reorganizing of
the TX Team One under a clearer program and a better understanding of
what our strategic and tactical goals are.” This statement also aligns
with what this comrade wrote in the November 2020 USW organizing update
in reference to the reformist practice of the Prisoner Human Rights
Movement (PHRM):
“unless anti-imperialist, revolutionary nationalist and/or communists
take hold of this movement and see it as a tactical operation instead of
a be-all end-all and thereby re-center the movement, it may only further
‘Amerikanize’ the (only) vastly-proletarian revolutionary sector of
society we have (lumpen in prison). That could occur if cats become
pacified with all these tokens and reforms that have been struggled
for.”
But just because we re-center a movement along these lines and dress
future demands to the state in sufficiently ‘revolutionary’ language to
avoid the perception of reformism does not mean that we are actually
avoiding these same pitfalls.
Here I will argue that even with an explicitly revolutionary program
guiding us in the struggle for tactical reforms, we can still be
susceptible to a sort of unwitting crypto-reformism if our struggles are
not chosen very carefully and with the correct tactical,
strategic and narrative approach. In the original commentary I wrote
that
“we should not be trying to ‘improve’ Amerikan prisons, much like we
should not be attempting to cut a bigger portion of imperialist profits
from Third World super-exploitation for the lower class, yet still
relatively privileged, citizens of empire.”
This statement meshes with your desire not to have strictly-reformist
campaigns “further ‘Amerikanize’ the (only) vastly-proletarian
revolutionary sector of society we have.” Of course our current approach
differs strategically from the reformists but, noble intentions aside,
it is still having the same overall effect in practice: we are
inadvertently pacifying individuals, making them complacent sleepwalkers
again. You may probably think: ‘Bullshit. We are teaching the masses
not to fall for any old reform, that these are ’tactical
maneuvers’,etc. And you may very well be able to indoctrinate a core of
cadre to hold strong to a political line which promotes this view.
However, if we view matters through a historical lens, when concessions
from the state were achieved via a revolutionary stage of struggle these
victories largely blunted the sympathetic masses desire to seek further
redress by way of revolutionary means. Whether that be (to cite a
non-Maoist, yet anti-capitalist example) during the peak of IWW
organizing a century ago, the transient successes of the
anti-revisionist New Communist Movement era or our current campaigns to
‘Abolish the SHU’ and ‘Release the Kids in Kages.’ Our ‘successes’ end
up serving as a pressure-release for many and creating a ‘kinder,
gentler machine-gun hand’ for our opponents to use against us, akin to
replacing the arrogance and political incorrectness of Trump for the
soothing reassurances of Biden.
From the commentary of the same USW organizing update from November
2020, you write that
“from an anti-imperialist perspective, the PHRM is only a tactic, a
means to an end. That end being, sharpening the contradiction between
oppressed and oppressor nations, and advancing the oppressed aspect of
that contradiction.”
But how do we really expect to sharpen the contradiction between
oppressed and oppressor nations and advance the oppressed aspect of that
contradiction if we are actively participating in the lowering or
resolution of the contradictions which heightened tensions in the first
place? There is a periodic ebb and flow of the revolutionary tide in
this country; why do we by way of our current tactical, strategic and
narrative approach inadvertently help turn an upswing into a downturn?
Of course the inherent contradiction in (note:their) Amerikan
society will never truly go away absent revolution, but we are in the
meantime attempting to apply balm to their societal problems
and in effect delay its arrival.
Circling back to the arguments put forth in ‘An Ongoing Discussion on
Organizing Strategy’, you bring up a good question when you write
that
“the real crux of the issue, as it pertains to linking a totalizing
revolutionary strategy, lies in practical experience gained by the
masses in asserting their collective power. For, how will we seize state
power if the people lack the strategic confidence to assert their
power?”
As my position does not advocate pushing for more quality-of-life
reforms even if there happens to be some positive by-product in cadre
development, my reply to this question is that we should re-orient our
tactics, strategy and narrative approach to the masses by
over-emphasizing self-reliance and independence-mastery on the
road to communist revolution. Therefore we should largely abstain from
trying to prevent erosions of their bourgeois legal rights such as
affirmative action, LGBTQ rights, abortion access, etc. and, if we are
to engage in any tactical reforms to begin with, instead focus on
opposition to proposals to place limits on magazine capacity, bans on
assault rifles and other perceived or actual threats to their 2nd
Amendment and other measures which will aid in our ability to maneuver
and take them down when the time comes. This of course does not
mean that we don’t support LGBTQ rights or abortion access, but fighting
for their (re:Amerika’s) civil liberties and other bourgeois
rights keeps many, including some well-meaning comrades, from seeing the
bigger picture: Let their country go to hell. The Amerikan
government will not become any less imperialist by advocating for more
rights for more people within U.S. borders and it is debatable that we
are contributing to anything more than a temporary weakening of
imperialism domestically. If anything we are contributing to its further
consolidation under the guise of new exploiters with more varied
genders, orientations and skin tones.
Our cadre and the masses will gain practical experience and strategic
confidence in their power by continuing to focus on construction of
independent institutions, not making demands of an illegitimate
government to provide redress. In the prison context, I repeat: “if we
are to engage in any prison organizing, then censorship battles
concerning our political ideology, the UFPP and the Re-Lease on Life
programs should take center stage… As for our comrades who do not have
the luxury of a release date, or have sentences which essentially
translate into the same, their best hope for release lies not in reforms
but with an all-sided MLM revolutionary organization planning their
release through eventual People’s War.”
Bypass the reforms which do not help us either strengthen our
party/cell formations, build independent institutions for the people or
hasten People’s War.
Say ‘NO’ to negotiations; focus on revolutionary-separation and
self-determination.
Wiawimawo of MIM(Prisons) responds: I want to thank
Triumphant and S. Xanastas for their thoughtful articulations on this
topic. And i hope that printing these in ULK are helpful to
others in thinking about how to organize effectively under the United
Struggle from Within banner or on the streets.
In my many years of working on this project i would say this two-line
struggle is really at the heart of what we do. Of course, how we walk
the line between ultra-left and rightism is always at the heart of those
deciding strategy for a communist movement. But these comrades address
this question in our context today in the United $tates and in the
context of organizing the First World lumpen and engaging in
prison-based organizing.
In all contexts, going too far left means isolating ourselves from
the masses and going too far right means tailing the masses and
following them into dead ends. Therefore finding the correct path also
requires determining who are the masses in our conditions. If we did not
agree on who the masses are then we could not have this discussion in a
meaningful way. Since we do agree, this is a two line struggle within
our movement. With that frame I want to quickly address a couple points
brought up here.
First, I think the strength in Triumphant’s argument is not in the
skill-building of the individual cadre leaders as organizers, which
arguably could be found elsewhere, but rather “in practical experience
gained by the masses in asserting their collective power.” Triumphant
also talks about the importance of the tactical battles in “increas[ing]
the collective practical experience of contesting the state as a united
body.”
S. Xanastas’ suggested program echoes closely to what Narobi Äntari’s
calls for comrades to do upon release. And they echo much of
MIM(Prisons) focus, especially in more recent years. Yet, i pose the
question: can building the Re-Lease on Life and University of Maoist
Thought programs mobilize and reach the masses in the same way as the
campaigns making demands from the state?
And one final point, is that MIM always said the principal task was
not just to build independent institutions of the oppressed, but also to
build public opinion against imperialism. Isn’t a campaign exposing the
widespread use of torture in U.$. prisons an undermining of U.$.
imperialism regardless of the maneuvers the various states make to cut
back on or hide their use of long-term isolation? Or should we focus
solely on the Third World neo-colonies and expose U.$. meddling in
Ethiopia, Cuba and Haiti?
The following is a response to some topics of debate within the
article “Maoist
Third Worldism: Responding to Criticism from a Reader” by Mazur of
the blog Struggle Sessions. “Maoist” projects in the United
States have put forth a number of lines in recent years as worthy of
dividing over. In our mind, there is none more important than the class
structure of this country. And if anyone wants to attempt a follow up to
Mazur’s effort, we request they respond to Imperialism
and its Class Structure in 1997 by MC5, rather than some ideas in
your head about what MIM Thought is.
Value and Price
Struggle Sessions asserts that the proponents of unequal
exchange between imperialism and the oppressed nations (i.e.: finished
goods and export commodities are unbalanced in such a way that the
countries whose wealth is being extracted are given a raw deal) couch
their views in part on a belief that the price of a given commodity is
set as equal across different countries. To that allegation we reply: in
what ‘Third Worldist’ publication has this been written? To my knowledge
MIM has not claimed this, nor was this asserted by the earlier
contributor. Cite your sources. Do not attempt to employ a selective
choice of academics as a stand-in with an eye towards deceiving your
online readership by purposefully distorting matters to the benefit of
your dogmatic conception of economic affairs and reality. That is why it
is easy for you to tear down your chosen academic-as-foil such as in
your statement that:
Amin would later adopt this to equalize price levels so that a given
use value costs the same in U.S. as it does in Guatemala. Before getting
into this this is just not true anyways…
You perceive yourself as rather clever, don’t you. We wonder into
what other topics of discussion you have inserted such imperious
analysis and judgments which have also resorted to similar rhetorical
deceptions and sleights-of-hand. Also, if our stance on unequal exchange
was really a “less sophisticated version” as you claim, wouldn’t you
just stick to picking apart that easier prey instead? So we see again
that you, Mazur, have run into problems, problems concerning deceit and
faulty logic in equal measure.
You are at least correct on one thing, and that is your statement
that your academic could not stand the test of Marxism. So let’s drop
any other “version that is worth using” and stick with Marxian
economics. And by Marxian economics, we do not refer merely to its
classical conception (it is worth noting that Marx claimed even he was
not a Marxist, alluding to the fact that Marxism is a living science,
ever changing and developing new insights, not static and impervious to
advances in economic complexity over time); we also refer to its
continuity within a Leninist framework in the era of imperialism,
super-exploitation and the labor aristocracy, which Lenin gave clarity
to and which MIM Thought has further expanded upon through materialist
analysis.
You allege that in our analysis we deliberately ignore the labor
theory of value. So, we will begin with Marx:
What, then, is the value of laboring power? Like that of
every other commodity, its value is determined by the quantity of labor
necessary to produce it. (1)
‘Value’ in its final form must correspond to the labor power embodied
in a given commodity. Yet properly gauging this has become more complex
under imperialism. The main way we have typically measured it is through
its price, its exchange value. This follows what is termed the law of
value, but, when commodities and the labor embodied in them (what is
termed ‘dead labor’) are transferred from the developing peripheries to
an imperialist nation via multinational corporations, the connection of
value to its price is distorted to the point where the product (your
banana) is finally placed in the produce section at an American
supermarket, so much super-profits have accrued from not paying the
Guatemalan workers the value of their labor that upon its sale there is
enough excess profit for the United Fruit Co. to in turn bless its
American management and warehouse employees with more than the
value of their labor, in effect purchasing their allegiance to where
they no longer have just their ‘chains’ to lose. They have become
invested in the continuation of super-exploitation of the Guatemalan
proletariat as have many additional Americans in their role as
consumers, fresh off the job in your glorified manufacturing sector, who
purchase the produce (yes, despite paying over its market value in
Guatemala “and regular distribution and retail costs, the speculative
costs of the money market, etc.”) and, being entitled to similar wage
privileges, can also afford to have their money manager include shares
of United Fruit in their investment portfolio, if they so choose. As for
our plantation worker: “In Guatemala, where the minimum wage is roughly
$11 a day” and workers “struggle to bring home even $220 a month” (2),
they may not have the luxury of being able to afford the very product of
their own toil without first considering whether it will cut into other
essential purchases or payments owed, despite it selling for close to
its actual value. The logic behind these processes are so elementary
that all but those who are ‘so intelligent, they are stupid’ cannot fail
to comprehend it. This is on display when you surprisingly acknowledge
that this wealth transfer happens to the extent we describe, yet
simultaneously are unable to understand or remain willfully ignorant of
its far-reaching implications. You state:
“Because of capital export it does indeed follow that the U.S. is a
net importer of commodities and that there is a stratum of monopoly
capitalists who derive their profits solely from interest from their
direct foreign investment that melts down to this strata …”
But, not to be deterred, you say that exploitation happens at the
point of production and the lazy dogmatist in you resurfaces as you go
on to state further:
“… but the U.S. is still the second largest manufacturer in the
world, behind only China. This is something the ‘TWist’ does not want to
recognize, that the class which has nothing to lose but its chains is
concentrated in large numbers in the USA.”
Who is
proletarian? Are they a revolutionary vehicle?
We are glad that we can agree that the proletariat is the class that
has nothing to lose but its chains. But the relevance of manufacturing
statistics we find confusing. Once again, you do not want to recognize
the full extent of this wealth transfer, but this time as it plays out
in the domestic manufacturing sector:
“They can’t compete with China in terms of labor. An American
manufacturing employee makes an average of $26 an hour, while his or her
Chinese counterpart makes only $5 an hour, according to the Reshoring
Institute.”(3)
American manufacturing operations are still dependent on raw
materials and parts with unpaid-for embodied labor within them that is
obtained under a system of super-exploitation and shipped across borders
for Amerikan workers to tinker with. This results in wages that are at
least five times higher and above the value of their labor because there
is enough money being made for the capitalists to both turn a profit and
purchase their allegiance. When you deny the hidden transfer of value
between national economies, perhaps it makes sense to estimate the size
of the proletariat based on GDP numbers as Mazur does above. The United
States being “the second largest manufacturer” only proves that a lot of
value is being realized here, not where that value is coming from.
While, we do not recall anyone ever not recognizing that
some Amerikan workers are employed in the manufacturing sector, the one
thing we do not equate them with is being a part of the proletariat.
Lenin reexamined the meaning of ‘proletarian’ in a more nuanced manner
when he said:
“The Roman proletarian lived at the expense of society. Modern
society lives at the expense of the modern proletarian. Marx
specifically stressed this profound observation of Sismondi. Imperialism
somewhat changes the situation.”(4)
The proletariat can most accurately be described as the social group
that is the revolutionary vehicle. This does not mean that it is
synonymous with the industrial working class for all times and contexts.
Mao understood this when he harnessed the immense latent power of the
Chinese peasantry, who at the time made up around 95% of the population.
They became the revolutionary vehicle while the industrial workers, due
in part to their marginal proportions, assumed more of an auxiliary
role. Would you also embrace the lazy dogmatism of the Trotskyists who
cling to their orthodoxy with a religious fervor and state that, because
the peasantry is not the industrial working class, it cannot be capable
of being the backbone of a revolution? History showed us otherwise,
while you would have been as insistent as Chen Duxiu and got nothing
accomplished. No, Mazur, in this matter you are much like the ‘Marxists’
who see Cuba or China as socialist. How so? Because you identify things
based on their form rather than their substance. You have lost the
ability (if you were ever able) of discerning who is revolutionary and
who is not, who are our friends and who are likely to betray us to
protect their stake in the system. You see occupations instead of
workers economic co-optation within that occupation by way of a
reactionary vested interest in their allegiance to empire and its
spoils. This makes you no different than the ‘Communists’ of yesteryear
who saw workers in hardhats attacking demonstrators protesting U.S.
involvement in Vietnam as objectively revolutionary, or the socialist
parties who supported their nations’ entrance into imperialist world
wars as to the workers’ benefit at the munitions plants:
“Thus, on the outbreak of the imperialist war in 1914 the parties of
the social-traitors in all countries, when they supported the
bourgeoisie of their ‘own’ countries, always and consistently explained
that they were acting in accordance with the will of the working class.
But they forgot that, even if that were true, it must be the task of the
proletarian party in such a state of affairs to come out against the
sentiments of the majority of the workers and, in defiance of them, to
represent the historical interests of the proletariat.”(5)
This is why when you say that our line leads one to the inevitable
conclusion that the working class in the U.S. and other imperialist
countries are the main exploiting class of the people of the world and
that “this would make the task of Communists to divide and discourage
the just rebellion of the masses,” we would concur, save for the whole
bit of rhetorical flourish about it being a ‘just rebellion.’
But you continue harping on that the imperialist working class faces,
in your words:
“… exploitation in many forms, with work speed-ups, greater temporary
contracts, de-skilling, through greater constant capital being
introduced and wage depression.”
Clearly such things applied to even an exploiter working class would
still benefit the capitalists. We do not claim that these workers are
insulated from unfair working conditions despite benefiting from their
relationship with imperialism, as they remain the subordinate partner in
this role. But we do not go so far as to label it ‘exploitation,’
because being ‘exploited’ is a very precise Marxist term. We would like
to make clear that this does not mean that by extension we believe that
no one faces conditions of exploitation within the imperialist centers,
nor do we “contend that there is no proletariat to organize in the
imperialist countries.” The previous ‘TWist’ contributor also did not
claim this. They criticized you for arguing “that the labor aristocracy
is not the majority class in the first world” (emphasis ours).
MIM(Prisons) has this to say:
“Our claims, however, are far from this. Our claim is that the masses
here are a minority force: they are oppressed nation, they are migrants,
they are prisoners, etc. We have been saying this for many years, yet
[our critics] ignore this line and claim that we do not believe that
anyone is oppressed in the First World. We don’t claim that there are no
masses here, we claim that the constantly dying imperialist system needs
to fall in order for proletarianization of the labor aristocracy to
happen.”(6)
We can look to segments of the internal semi-colonies including the
over 500 Indigenous nations on the continent, sectors of the Third World
diaspora including the so-called ‘illegal’ migrant workers residing
within imperialist borders, the revolutionary youth and intellectuals,
and the revolutionized lumpen and prison populations as wellsprings for
our revolutionary mass base in this country. But you would, again,
looking at form rather than substance, likely scoff at this and act like
we are just going to accept and network with these groups uncritically
as we encounter them and not pursue their further proletarianization.
This is not the case. We also express with a higher degree of actual
confidence and certainty that the above-mentioned groups have a greater
interest in seeing the tables turned in this country, and turned
violently, than your bourgeoisified working classes you seek to lose
yourselves in.
And note: it is at this point that, having just detailed
our position clearly and corrected the record, we will formally ask you
to cease claiming that we believe that there are no proletarians or
masses within the imperialist centers to practice the mass line
with. Quote us correctly. Honesty may not come naturally
to you, but those who stumble across this blog page deserve a truthful
and accurate representation of views other than your own. You can only
deceive the masses for so long before they find out and call you on your
bullshit. On a related note, it is amusing (while incorrect) that you
paint proponents of the labor aristocracy-maturation line as “largely
abstentionists from revolutionary practice” when we can observe the
prison ministry of the MIM testing its ideas, struggling with the
imprisoned masses and developing theory through practice. Providing this
leadership and developing new cadre in the prisons while retaining
fidelity to anti-imperialism and the international proletariat is a
verifiable practice of theirs. On the other hand, it remains to be seen
how you and your lazy dogmatist cohorts will translate such fine
rhetoric as “recogniz[ing] the importance of organizing the proletariat
[in the manufacturing sectors] as a vital trench, to defeat
imperialism’s political influence through the labor aristocracy among
the proletariat” into concrete policies and actions.
Role of
Consumption in Determining Our Friends
You are quick to dismiss arguments about Amerikan access to wealth by
saying that as real Marxists we know that exploitation happens at the
point of production,
“We see then that exploitation does not happen at the level of
circulation. It happens at production as will be explained further
below.”
Yet we do not argue that the proletariat is being exploited at the
supermarket. Rather we are saying that surplus value is calculated by
the simple arithmetic of subtracting value received by the worker from
the value added by the worker. Therefore, increasing value received has
the potential of creating a negative value on the right-hand side of
that equation; surplus value can be negative. Of course this can only be
true for a subset of so-called workers or capital would cease to
circulate.
You take another grain of truth from Marx and extrapolate it
inappropriately in your sentence:
“For TWists who distort Marxism, the greater amount of use values a
wage can command=the lesser degree of exploitation of a waged
worker.”
Marx’s model predicts an increase in use values becoming available to
the proletariat, and even becoming part of the value of labor (the basic
cost of survival). An example of this would be that by 2018, 83% of
adults in Third World countries had a cell phone.(7) Banking and other
services are often only available in remote regions via cell phone.
Therefore, having a cell phone in general would not be a good indicator
of the degree of exploitation someone faced in 2018. Whereas in 1990, it
was a good indicator that you were not exploited.
You continue,
“Pure and simple, a temp worker at a plastic shop earning 25,000 in
the USA doesn’t exploit anyone, while a food production small business
owner in Managua who earns less than 25,000 who has employees who earn
less than what he does exploits – exploitation requires a position of
ownership and control over the means of production.”
While 86% of adults in Kenya have a cell phone (less than half of
those have smart phones), the average consumption of the poorest 20% of
Amerikans is about 10 times that of the average Kenyan.(8) What economic
logic would Struggle Sessions use to justify enjoying use
values an order of magnitude greater than those in the Third World,
while maintaining that both groups are exploited proletarians with
nothing to lose but their chains? Here you argue that an Amerikan making
more money than a Nicaraguan has more revolutionary potential. What
happened to “nothing to lose but their chains”?
Another metric provided at the website above is the number of Big
Mac’s a McDonald’s worker can buy with one hour of wages in 2007. An
Amerikan working at McDonald’s at that time could buy 6 times as many
Big Macs as an Indian working the same job.(8) Will Struggle
Sessions argue that the Amerikan is more productive flipping
burgers? Not to mention the fact that most Amerikans are now engaged in
service work like this where the possibility for great increases in
productivity don’t even exist as they do in manufacturing.
From there we must ask, what systems of militarism, war, borders and
financial manipulations must be maintained to keep that differential
between the Amerikan McDonald’s worker and the Indian one? And how does
Struggle Sessions propose we can organize these Amerikan
McDonald’s workers to oppose militarism, war, borders and international
finance manipulating the economies of the Third World?
Pray tell, comrade, how are you going to combat the siren
song of the labor aristocracy in their workplaces, especially when you
fail to even properly recognize who is and isn’t a part of the labor
aristocracy? And we ask, are you going to offer less
opportunities to fight for ill-gotten spoils of imperialism? No, that
won’t do it, no. So not only are you going to 1) hop into the ‘trench’
of worker privilege, valiantly protecting and further fattening the
bloated hourly earnings of production workers, their pension plans and
paid-vacation leave; but 2) you are going to attempt to convince them
that they should want to overthrow the government and corporations which
supply their cushy material existence; following that up by 3) asking
them to be on board with a future reduction in pay and standard
of living to pursue the objective of an equal global distribution of
wealth and reparations to the Global South; and 4) all the while being
supportive of a proposal for a demilitarized, open border with Mexico so
that the working classes of all nations can pursue better employment
opportunities?
Mazur, we can’t even say that we wish you luck (and certainly not on
the first point); just that it’ll be the workers themselves, not their
employers or security, picking you up and throwing you out of the
factory floor and onto your ass. But go ahead and falsify our thesis and
you will effectively accomplish what no amount of keyboard clattering on
your part can do at present. That is essentially what it comes down to.
Show us. Moreover, do so without inadvertently activating
social-fascism.
Applying Marxism to Our
Conditions
In the 100-odd years since the first successful revolution leading to
a dictatorship of the proletariat, none have occurred in an imperialist
country with the industrial working classes as the revolutionary
vehicle. You acknowledge we are right in pointing this out. Yet you
still cannot comprehend the full gravity of the labor aristocracy
maturation-line to know that the reasons that you cite for this failure
(fascism, revisionism) are intrinsically tied up with a failure on the
part of Communist organizations to determine the true extent of the rot
and subsequently to cease catering to the labor aristocracy’s demands
altogether. The problem lies in part with the fact that you believe (as
if it were still the second decade of the last century, not the current
one) that:
“The reality is such a condition for labor aristocracy is rooted
fundamentally in the opportunist political leadership of sections of
organized labor, courting favor with U.S. imperialism in competition on
a world scale. It was never defined, by Lenin, Mao or any other past
revolutionary movement from among the oppressed nations and proletariat,
as a strata that encapsulated the entirety of the working class (white
or otherwise) of the ‘First World.’”
Lazy dogmatism rears its head once more when you go referencing the
classics without taking into account the particular dynamics of our ever
deeper progression into the imperialist era and our unique geographic
location within it. Chairman Gonzalo had something to say about people
doing just that while expounding on the need to better understand Maoism
and struggle for its supremacy. In our quest to promote a better
understanding of the full implications of the labor aristocracy
maturation-line and the necessity to struggle for that line over the
ossified views of our erring Maoist fellow travelers, we will quote him
at length (we feel that, if nothing else gets their attention perhaps
quoting him will be the spark necessary to get the ‘Principally
Maoists’ to correct their thinking on the matter):
“In order to better understand Maoism and the necessity to struggle
for it, let us remember Lenin. He taught us that as the revolution
advanced in the East it expressed specific conditions that, while they
did not negate principles or laws, were new situations that Marxism
could not ignore, upon the risk of putting the revolution in danger of
defeat. Notwithstanding the uproar against what is new by pedantic and
bookish intellectuals, who are stuffed with liberalism and false
Marxism, the only just and correct thing to do is to apply Marxism
to the concrete conditions and to solve the new situations and problems
that every revolution necessarily faces. In the face of the
horrified and pharisaic ‘defenses of the ideology, the class, and of the
people’ that revisionists, opportunists, and renegades proclaim, or the
furious attacks against Marxism by brutalized academicians and hacks of
the old order who are debased by the rotten bourgeois ideology and
blindly defend the old society on which they are parasites. Lenin also
said clearly that the revolution in the East would present new and great
surprises to the greater amazement of the worshipers of following only
the well-trodden paths who are incapable of seeing the new; and, as we
all know, he trusted the Eastern comrades to resolve the problems that
Marxism had not yet resolved.”(9) (emphasis ours)
We would add to Gonzalo’s statement that Lenin would have also
trusted the imperialist nation comrades to resolve the problems that
Marxism-Leninism had only begun to address and solve, and to not
mechanically parrot their words on the scope and potential solutions to
problems which in their time were but saplings compared to the broader
trunks and deeper roots which we must now contend with, axe in hand. The
labor aristocracy maturation-line, flowing from Lenin’s
analysis of the split in the working class movement in the early 20th
century with its antecedents in Marx and Engels’ analysis of the English
working class in the 19th century, contends that this split has only
continued and with minimal interruption for the past 100 years in the
imperialist centers, absorbing whole sectors of the working classes,
bribed now in a thousand more ways than before. It was impossible for
Marx, Engels and Lenin to examine and address these issues as well as we
can today, because they were a relatively new development at the time.
We, however, now have the extensive benefit of hindsight, history and
statistics not available then. Yet Lenin did direct our attention to its
creeping progression:
“The longer bourgeois democracy has prevailed in a country, the more
complete and well established it is, the more successful have the
bourgeoisie of that country been in getting into those leading positions
people who are reared in bourgeois democracy, saturated in its attitudes
and prejudice, and very frequently bribed by it, whether directly or
indirectly.”(10)
Mao also spoke on this subject:
“In the various nations of the West there is a great obstacle to
carrying through any revolution and construction movement, i.e., the
poisons of the bourgeoisie are so powerful that they have penetrated
each and every corner. While our bourgeoisie has had, after all, only
three generations, those of England and France have had a 250-300 year
history of development, and their ideology and modus operandi
have influenced all aspects and strata of their societies. Thus the
English working class follows the Labour Party, not the Communist
Party.”(11)
Because of this, Mao went on to disagree with Lenin:
“Lenin says, ‘the transition from capitalist to socialism will be
more difficult for a country the more backward it is.’ This would seem
incorrect today.”(12)
We can no longer point to just ‘the opportunist political leadership
of sections of organized labor’ and call them the whole of the labor
aristocracy. They now represent a class of workers who have become
bourgeois in outlook and have only grown exponentially over time. At
what point do you realize and accept that the imperialist nation
industrial working classes and service sectors are no longer a viable
revolutionary vehicle for Maoism, and that we must focus our organizing
in areas separate from these? At what point do things finally begin to
click into place for you, or are you allowing your pride and dogmatic
rote-learning to blind you to the reality which screams for recognition?
If for whatever reason hearing this message from us in particular is
just too much to stomach, then we recommend the book Labor
Aristocracy: Mass Base of Social Democracy by H.W. Edwards for more
detailed analysis. We encourage everyone with an inquiring mind to not
just take our word for it – examine our references and arrive at the
necessary conclusions on this important subject matter. Do not allow
idealism or lazy dogmatism to cloud your judgment any longer to the
futility of throwing yourself against the wall of the labor aristocracy
in your organizing efforts.
There are two final matters we would like to address. The first is
that it is said we have come by our views through and subsequent traffic
in “petty-bourgeois empiricism-posing-as-analysis,” to which we
reply:
“The lazy dogmatists actually see no real role for science in
agitations. In response to Mao’s proof that line is decisive, they
accept at face value the revisionist slander that calls Mao idealist. By
downplaying science, they pave the way for fascism, which consciously
relies on mysticism for victory in people’s hearts. They imagine that
being good Maoists means being idealist, not practitioners of the
science of Marxism-Leninism-Maoism.”(13)
By criticizing our use of statistics, percentages and numbers, you
are by extension leveling your criticism at Lenin:
“Lenin used many more such statistics, including Tsarist statistics
and criticized those who would not make much use of them.”(14)
Our critics don’t like it when we use basic addition and subtraction
to show that their math doesn’t add up.(15) We must remind our readers
of this line:
“For TWists who distort Marxism, the greater amount of use values a
wage can command=the lesser degree of exploitation of a waged
worker.”
Does that mean you believe the inverse? As First Worldists you
believe that material wealth can increase infinitely without
disqualifying one from being exploited? Must we bring up the old NFL
player example and ask if they have nothing to lose but their chains?
And to pivot to our final topic, Colin Kaepernick was protesting the
murder of young Black men in the streets by the state, not wages or
working conditions. Same reason cities burned across the country last
year, and the same reason they’ve burned almost every other time in the
last 60 years.
Nations
We find your agnosticism on the national question problematic, “In
regards to the white nation, we [Struggle Sessions] have not
taken a formal position on this.” First we are in the era of
imperialism, which is defined by the contradiction between nations. To
not be able to address the national question in one’s own country is to
fail to address the whole of modern political economy. Second, the
question of first importance is who are our friends, and who are our
enemies. To not have a line on the nature of the euro-Amerikan nation,
while having a very well worked out line on military strategy in the
United $tates (a line we know is dear to the hearts of Struggle
Sessions authors), is a dangerous example of putting the cart
before the horse.
To address the question as you raise it, we will begin by saying that
U.S. imperialism is a multinational project in two respects. The first
pertains specifically to the makeup of the Euro-Amerikan oppressor
nation, and the second in the national-patriotic sense with the
inclusion of token elements of the New Afrikan and Latin@ bourgeoisie in
leadership positions both in business and government and the
participation of their respective labor aristocracies in the plunder of
the Global South. But our focus is in addressing the seeming paradox of
the Euro-Amerikan Nation, and whether it is myth or fact. You state
that:
“In this case they are lumping a bunch of languages, cultures,
regions and psychologies into one nation. For instance the psychological
makeup of Jews, Slavs, Irish and Anglo Americans are not the same, and
their languages are often different, too.”
The Euro-Amerikan Nation (or ‘white’ nation in more simplified terms)
has historically assumed the role of dominant oppressing force since the
founding of the United States. Being ‘white’ in America is not only so
much a matter of genealogy and physiognomy as it is one of hierarchy,
both in terms of class and nation. We agree that these people were
something else before they were ‘white’ or Euro-Amerikan – Corsican,
Welsh, Jewish, German etc. Yet through a common historical bond rooted
in violence, rape and looting of labor and land, began a process of
washing the disparate tribes white, a belief in being ‘white,’ becoming
a unified, melded nation in the patriotic and national sense. In the
United States, the separate Irish, Anglo, Polish, etc. immigrant
nationalities of old are now mostly forgotten ‘dead nations,’ with
forgotten mother tongues, blended beyond recall save in surname or
remnant cultural practice seldom exercised in day-to-day existence. They
have transformed themselves over the generations into a single unit
sharing a common culture, language (English), economy (within the
borders of the U.S. excluding most other nations) and territorial
cohesion (again, much of North America). Your denial of this could only
be justified by some racial theory of bloodline.
For you to say that ‘there is no common economy, there is no common
language, there is no geographic territory, and so on’ is an ahistorical
delusion that serves no purpose whatsoever. By denying this, it would
seem that by extension you would also deny the same ‘nation’ status for
the ‘Black’ or New Afrikan Nation, and furthermore any right to their
own self-determination because ‘at best’ you see several nations that,
through participation in the brutal receiving end of the
settler project in the past, were able to achieve uneven status and
integration into ‘blackness.’ (Mazur links to a now official paper by
Struggle Sessions that addresses the intersection of so-called
“race” and class in relation to New Afrika. For now, we will present MIM
Theory 7 as a counter to that piece.)
The Great Migration of Black sharecroppers to the industrial north
and west in the early to mid 20th century dispersed the population of
the Black Belt south throughout the modern colonial borders of the
United States. Nonetheless, New Afrikans constitute a nation as a result
of the historical (forced) melding of different cultures, languages and
psychologies into a new and unique shared culture, language and segments
of territory. It is our hope to one day see the will of the New Afrikan
Nation expressed in a plebiscite on self-determination. Perhaps Mazur
& Co. will be on the right side of history when this occurs.
One final note, we are in agreement with the statement that:
“‘Privilege’ itself, as well as the absence of national oppression,
does not in any way actually prevent those with a relative ‘privilege’
from facing oppression and exploitation as well.”
The white youth, intellectuals and revolutionized white lumpen and
prisoners have an interest in revolution as traitors to their class and
nation. We do not overextend our analysis to exclude these potential
allies in our struggle.
Notes: 1. Karl Marx, “Labouring Power,” Value, Price and
Profit, Martino Fine Books, 2017 p. 39. 2. Lauren Villagran, “A
Desperate Quest for American Dream Denied,” USA Today, December
23, 2020. 3. Michael Braga, “Manufacturers Facing Hurdles in Return
to US,” USA Today, December 22, 2020. It should be noted that
back in 2018, hourly earnings for production workers were pegged at
$22.71 according to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of
Labor. Thus a steady increase has occurred in 2 years’ time rather than
a trend towards wage suppression as our labor-aristocratic Maoists
allege. 4. V.I. Lenin, “Imperialism and the Split in Socialism,”
Lenin’s Struggle for a Revolutionary International: Documents
1907-1916, John Riddell, ed. New York: Monad Press, 1984
p. 497. 5. Jane Degras, ed. The Communist International:
1919-1943 Documents, London: Frank Cass & Co., 1971 Vol. 1,
p. 129 (hereafter Degras) 6. MIM (Prisons), “A Falsifiable Thesis,”
Who’s Got Something to Prove, JMP?, August 2020.
www.prisoncensorship.info 7.
Laura
Silver, 5 February 2019, Smartphone Ownership Is Growing Rapidly Around
the World, but Not Always Equally, Pew Research Center. 8.
https://www.justfacts.com/income_wealth_poverty#international 9.
Communist Party of Peru, “Introduction”, Fundamental
Documents. 10. Degras, Vol. 1, p. 119. 11. Mao Tsetung,
A Critique of Soviet Economics New York: Monthly Review Press,
1977 p. 50. 12. Ibid. 13. MIM Theory Number 10, “Lessons From
the Comintern: Continuities in Method and Theory, Changes in Theory and
Conditions”, Coming to Grips with the Labor Aristocracy, 1996.
p. 22. View PDF at www.prisoncensorship.info 14. Ibid., p. 42. See
Lenin’s “Statistics and Sociology,” Collected Works, Vol. 23.
Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1964. p. 271. For Mao talking about
dogmatist lazybones, see Mao Tse-Tung, “On Contradiction,” Four
Essays on Philosophy. Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1968
p. 37. 15. MC5, 1997, Imperialism
and its Class Structure in 1997, part C.5..
Responses
MIM(Prisons) submitted this response to Struggle Sessions.
While no response has been received yet, we cannot expect from them in
days, what took us many months. However, we have already received some
astute responses from others that we are including here.
ADDENDUM
1: A comment on ‘Mazur’s’ understanding of unequal exchange
by marlax1g
The theory of unequal exchange of Samir Amin is one thing, the theory
of Arghiri Emmanuel is another. I do not know if MIM ever commented on
the distinction between the two theories (perhaps for political purposes
given the overwhelming First Worldist hysteria surrounding it), but the
theory of unequal exchange ‘in the strict sense’ as based on global wage
differentials is what MIM (and also Cope’s 2012 book) have always made
reference to; ‘Imperialism and its Class Structure in 1997’ makes
explicit reference to wage differentials in Section
A Chapter 5-6
and Section
C Chapter 5. This theory does not depend upon either differing
organic compositions or differing productivities within the same branch
of trade. And Emmanuel’s criticism of the doctrine of comparative
advantage does not depend upon a criticism of the quantity theory of
money, as he implies in quite literally one of the first paragraphs of
the Introduction. The reference to declining terms of trade in Emmanuel
has absolutely nothing to do with the distinction between primary and
non-primary commodities (explicitly contrary to the Prebisch–Singer
hypothesis), but rather with the wages in the two sectors. Let us note
one more error on the part of Mazur before we get around to explaining
where the error arises.
“If there are the same prices and the wages in the U.S. are higher,
and capital goods costs the same, then the cost price of any given
commodity would be higher in the U.S. This means (since the price of the
finished commodity is the same) that the rate of profit would be lower
in the U.S., so no transfer would even take place.”
Let’s start from the basics. Ricardo’s theory of comparative costs
represents a “special” case where the labor theory of value is
invalidated. The labor theory does not govern prices at an international
level, Ricardo states, because profits cannot equalize. Profits may
equalize within nations because capital is mobile, but it cannot
equalize between nations where capital is immobile as such immobility
results in specialization and therewith the governing of comparative as
opposed to absolute cost. Wages do not enter into Ricardo’s equation
because he operated under the assumption that wages tended towards the
subsistence level because of the Malthusian law of population. (In other
words, Ricardo takes equal wages as a given.)
Marx overthrew the Malthusian “iron law of wages” and this fact is
the starting point for Emmanuel. What Emmanuel emphasizes is a world
where capital is mobile, and therefore profits do indeed tend towards an
equality, but where the Marxian law of exogenous wages rules. Why does
this matter? Because labor is not mobile, and because wages in the First
World are in fact higher without being subject to the discipline of
equalization, wages are the only ‘independent variable’ governing global
prices of production. It is no argument against Emmanuel to claim that
he abandons the labor theory of value, because in the real world market
prices fluctuate around not values but rather prices of production.
Perhaps Mazur missed the publication of Volume Three of Capital, but
Emmanuel had not. Hence “factor rewards” (namely wages) are not given by
prices, but rather prices are given by “factor rewards” (in neoclassical
parlance). Emmanuel therefore inverts the logic of
Hecksher-Ohlin-Samuelson: prices do not determine wages, but rather
wages prices. This is Emmanuel avec Marx.
The products of industries employing workers at low wages, therefore,
have relatively low prices, and those which employ workers at high wages
have relatively high prices. This is precisely the point of Emmanuel’s
argument — because we are dealing with different commodities being
exchanged. Critics of Emmanuel imagine that they are intelligent in
coming to the profound conclusion that high wages translate into a lower
rate of surplus-value and therefore profit. Emmanuel does not deny this;
he instead shows that with an equalizing profit rate the surplus-value
of the Third World is transferred to the First World because products of
low prices are exchanged for products of high prices. It’s really quite
that simple. And to repeat ourselves for the tenth time, the prices are
high and low because of differing wages. To believe otherwise is nothing
more than marginalism. Emmanuel’s argument is not, in fact, that unequal
exchange is preferable to lower wages in the First World from the
viewpoint of the capitalist; it is only that the lack of wage
equalization partially compensates the drop in the rate of profit.
No child, us Third Worldists do not argue that super-profits
originate in circulation (a libel of Bettelheim), but rather in the
super-exploitation of the Third World proletariat. If they were not
super-exploited, if the rate of surplus-value was not in fact higher,
there would not have been enough surplus-value to transfer and either
First World wages or capitalism itself would have had to collapse.
Mazur writes that:
“Because the organic composition of capital has allowed much more
surplus value to actually be generated, we see then that the rate of
exploitation is often higher in spite of wage increases.”
Imagine such crass physicalism coming from an avowed defender of the
labor theory. Capital with a higher organic composition does not allow
“more surplus-value to actually be generated”. It quite literally
implies less variable capital (relative to its size) and therefore less
surplus-value because constant capital does not contribute an iota of
surplus-value. Mazur wants us to believe that because capital-intensity
is usually higher in the First World, this axiomatically makes First
World workers more “productive” of surplus-value. First Worldists have
never proven labor intensity is higher in the First World, which is what
this claim necessitates demonstrating. We have already seen that this
does not put a dent into Emmanuel’s theory, and Emmanuel explicitly (and
consequently) asserts that, e.g., First World primary producers
(Australian coal, Canadian timber, etc.) still benefit from unequal
exchange. But this is of course a mirage, and as soon as the parasitism
of the labor aristocracy confronts the “Marxist” defender of the labor
theory of value, they turn into John Bates Clark and want us to believe
that wages are governed by labor’s marginal productivity.
I could continue, and I would like to defend Sakai from the virulence
he has been subjected to, but I will leave that to someone perhaps more
competent than myself.
ADDENDUM 2: On Appalachia
loop-3: Given that MIM(Prisons) has no materialist
analysis of the region, and certainly no experience organizing within
it, it is unclear why you now incorrectly say that
“Poor whites in Appalachia… have an interest in revolution as
traitors to their class and nation. We do not overextend our analysis to
exclude these potential allies in our struggle.”
This is a striking political regression. The actual Maoist
Internationalist Movement had a far more correct position on this.
According to MC5,
“Often times we Marxists are told that we should go organize the
Appalachian poor for their economic demands. Duncan gives us some
up-to-date evidence on why that is a silly idea. Between 1980 and 1990,
Blackwell county shrunk in population by 12%. That is the real social
movement of Appalachia. Yes, there is a shortage of jobs, so people
move. That is why there is no class solidarity or class consciousness
that arises in Appalachia, no matter how many Marxists bang their heads
on the wall there. To the extent that Marxists do influence or awaken
anyone, they simply move or succeed in their middle-class ambitions. We
do not need Marxism for that and hence we find the subject matter of
Duncan’s book boring. It is about how to integrate people into
middle-class life. There is no other possibility when poverty is only in
isolated pockets and not a generalized economic condition within a
country’s borders…
“Even if Appalachia had closed borders, it would only then be
equivalent to some of the poorer European countries. At $15,321, central
Appalachia’s median income would still be more than 10 times higher than
that of the median for the international proletariat. Between 1980 and
1990 meanwhile, Gray Mountain’s income literally doubled.
“Both the Mississippi Delta and central Appalachia are shrinking in
population. Already in 1980, the two infamously poor regions combined
had only a population of 1.8 million in a country of 226.5 million with
open borders internally. In other words, they are less than one percent
of the population and it was ridiculous to expect any class formation
there. By 1990, the two regions combined shrunk to less than 1.7
million, or less than the number of people in prison today.
“The trillions in super-profits sucked out of the Third World make it
possible for whole countries to be rich like the United $tates. Although
inequalities continue to exist within the United $tates, they are not
nearly as central or as important to Marxists as those on a global
scale.”
In addition, MIM Theory 1, in the article “Pittston Strike Shows
Depth of White Working Class Alliance,” favorably quotes from this
section of J. Sakai’s Settlers on this issue:
“Despite the 60 years of repeated radical organizing drives [in
Appalachia] there has been, in fact, zero revolutionary progress among
the mining communities. Despite the history of bloody union battles,
class consciousness has never moved beyond an embryonic form, at best.
There is no indigenous [here, Sakai is referring to regional whites]
revolutionary activity - none - or traditions. Loyalty to U.S.
imperialism and hatred of the colonial peoples is very intense. We can
see a derailment of the connection between simple exploitation and class
consciousness…
“This points out the fact that what is poverty-stricken about
settlers is their culture.
“The Euro-Amerikan coal miners are just concentrating on ‘getting
theirs’ while it lasts. In the settler tradition it’s ‘every man for
himself’. They have no class goals or even community goals, just private
goals involving private income and private consumerism. Meanwhile, the
local N&W land manager says that they do have future plans for
Appalachia: ‘We don’t intend to walk off and leave this land to the
Indians’. Of that we can be certain.”
MIM(Prisons) respond: We thank loop-3 for pointing
this out and include eir well-cited argument here. And we have removed
the clause “poor whites in Appalachia” from that sentence as it was
misleading as if the class interests of that population somehow make
them more likely allies than anyone else in the white nation. We must be
cautious and clear when trying to organize Amerikans around their own
interests. While virtually everyone has some interests opposed to
imperialism, and anyone can end up a victim of the system, white
Amerikans must go against their class and nation (and gender) interests
to ally with the international proletariat and the communist project, as
S. Xanastas correctly pointed out in that paragraph.
White youth have more gender interest in revolution and are less
bought into their class and nation. White lumpen arguably have some
class interest different than other Amerikans. What is more clear is
that white lumpen will more often take an interest in revolutionary
politics when they are surrounded by oppressed nations in prison or part
of multi-national lumpen organizations. As for the intellectuals
mentioned, they do not have different interests so much as a different
view of the world. So it is in these groups that we see the greatest
percentage of exceptions to the rule – those who are willing to go
against their own class and nation interests and side against U.$.
imperialism.