27: "The International
Division of Labour"
The policy of national discrimination adopted in relation to the non-Russian Union Republics is "justified" theoretically in terms of what is called by contemporary Soviet economists the "law of the international division of labour". This "law" is of great importance not only internally, but also externally since it is utilised to "justify" the policy adopted towards the countries within Comecon and towards underdeveloped countries. Here, however, space precludes treatment of the external relations of the Soviet Union.
According to Marxism-Leninism, the value of a commodity is determined, as has been pointed out in Section 14 ("Price Control"), by the amount of socially necessary labour time involved in its production.
But the socially necessary labour time involved in the production of a particular commodity varies in different regions and in different countries according to such factors as climate, soil, accessibility to mineral resources and the productivity of labour (the latter depending on the technical level of production). Thus, the value of a particular commodity varies in different regions and in different countries:
(M. Senin: "Socialist Integration"; Moscow; 1973; p. 228-9).
(D. Ricardo: "The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation"; London; 1937; p. 80, 81).
Before Specialisation
Britain: 120 100 220
Total: 390
After Specialisation
Britain: - 200 200 20
___ ___
360 30
Ricardo refrains from carrying his theory to its logical conclusion -- that there would be an even greater total saving of labour if both cloth and wine were made in Portugal!
Many contemporary Soviet economists
endorse
at least "the rational basis" of Ricardo's theory:
Further
Wine Cloth Total Saving
Portugal: 160 180 340
Britain: - - -
___
Total: 340 20
The economists who see a rational grain in Ricardo's theory and think of using it to promote the international socialist division of labour are closer to the truth".
(M. Senin: ibid.; p. 233, 234).
(K. Marx: "Capital", Volume 3; London; 1974; p. 238).
(A.I. Chekhutov: "Economic Co-operation with Socialist States as a Factor of Industrialisation of Developign Countries"; Moscow; 1973; p. 234).
(K. Marx: "Histoire des doctrines economiques" (History of Economic Doctrines); Paris; n.d.; in: A. Emmanuel: "Unequal Exchange: A Study of the Imperialism of Trade"' London; 1972; p. 92).
(K. Marx: "Capital", Volume 3; London; 1974; p. 238).
"Under any circumstances there exists an international exchange which in every concrete case brings greater advantages to countries with a more developed economy, and less advantages to countries with a less developed economy".
(M. Senin: ibid.; p. 231, 235).
(M. Senin: ibid.; p. 63) as an objective economic law, namely:
"...the law of the international division of labour".
(M. Senin: ibid.; p. 57).
(V.I. Kuznetsov: "Economic Integration: Two Approaches"; Moscow; 1976; p. 41).
(F.D. Whitehouse: "Demographic Aspects of Regional Economic Development in the USSR", in: V.N. Bandera & Z.L. Melnyk (Eds.): "The Soviet Economy in Regional Perspective"; New York; 1973; p. 156).
(A.N. Kosygin: "Guidelines for the Development of the National Economy of the USSR", 25th. Congress CPSU; Moscow; 1976; p. 71).
Investment, as the term is used by contemporary Soviet economists, is the provision of new means of production to the economy.
Under the socialist system which formerly existed in the Soviet Union, new means of production were, as has been shown in the section entitled "Payment for Production Assets", allocated by the state to enterprises without charge, in accordance with the central state economic plan:
(V. Vorobyev: "Credit and Industrial Development", in: "Ekonomicheskaya gazeta" (Economic Gazette), No. 46, 1965, in: "The Soviet Economic Reforms: Main Features and Aims"; Moscow; 1967; p. 90).
"The financing of capital investment is currently handled by free grants from the state budget."
(A.N. Kosygin: "On Improving Industrial Management, Perfecting Planning and Enhancing Economic incentives in Industrial Production", in: "Izvestia" (News), September 28th., 1965, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed.): "Planning, Profit and Incentives in the USSR", Volume 2; New York; 1966; p. 23).
(V. Batyrev: "The Economic Reform and the Increasing Role of Credit", in: "Kommunist" (Communist), No. 2, 1966, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed.): op. cit., Volume 2; p. 246).
(P.G. Bunich: "Methods of Planning and Stimulation", in: "Soviet Economic Reform: Progress and Problems"; Moscow; 1972; p. 37).
(T.S. Khachaturov: "The Economic Reform and Efficiency of Investments", in: "Soviet Economic Reform: Progress and Problems"; Moscow; 1972; p. 156).
"In accordance with the decision of the September (1965 -- WBB) Plenary Meeting of the CPSU Central Committee, the volume of decentralised capital investments is being expanded considerably".
(P. Bunich: "Economic Stimuli to Increase the Effectiveness of Capital Investments and the Output-to-Capital Ratio", in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Problems of Economics), No. 12, 1965, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed.): op. cit., Volume 2; p. 185-6).
(I. Shur: "Long-term Credit in Industry", in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Problems of Economics), No. 6, 1970, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 13, No. 8; December 1970; p. 46).
Thus, some 78.8% of total investment comes from enterpirses' own funds.
For the purpose of making such investments, each enterprise is obliged to set up a production development fund:
c) a production development fund designated for investment by the enterprise".
(V.M. Batyrev: "Commodity-Money Relations under Socialism", in: "The Soviet Planned Economy"; Moscow; 1974; p. 172).
(R. Krylov, L. Rotshtein & D. Tsarev: "On the Procedure and Conditions for Changing to the New System", in: "Planovoe khoziaistvo" (Planned Economy), No. 4, 1966, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed.): op. cit., Volume 2; p. 267).
On the average, 40% of depreciation allowances are transferred to the enterprise's production development fund, the remaining 60% going to the state.
(R. Krylov, L. Rotshtein & D. Tsarev: ibid.; p. 267)
Thus,
(K.N. Plotnikov: "Soviet Finance and Credit", in: "The Soviet Planned Economy"; Moscow; 1974; p. 218).
(B. Sukharevsky: "New Elements in Economic Incentives", in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Prolems of Economics), No. 10, 1965, in: "The Soviet Economic Reform: Main Features and Aims"; Moscow; 1967; p. 80).
"Profit is a vitally important source of expanded socialist reproduction".
(L. Gatovsky: "The Role of Profit in a Socialist Economy", in: "Kommunist" (Communist), No. 18, 1962, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed.); op. cit., Volume 1; p. 89).
"The role of profit will also be reinforced as a source of the reproduction of fixed assets in the enterprises".
(B. Sukharevsky: "The Enterprise and Material Stimulation", in: "Ekonomicheskaya gazeta" (Economic Gazette), No. 49, 1965, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed): op. cit., Volume 2; p. 210).
(A.N. Kosygin: ibid.; p. 22-3).
Furthermore, between 1966 and 1970 enterprises' production development funds rose, on average by 6 times.
(N.Y. Drogichinsky: "The Economic Reform in Action", in: "Soviet Economic Reform: Progress and Problems"; Moscow; 1972; p. 207).
Any investment made by an enterprise over and above the funds available in its production development fund must (as has been shown in the sections entitled "Payment for Production Assets" and "Credit and Interest") normally be obtained in the form of bank credit, repayable by the enterprise with interest:
According to preliminary calculations, more than half of the present total volume of capital investments -- 20 to 25 thousand million rubles -- can be effectuated through credit".
(V. Garbuzov: "Finances and Economic Stimuli", in: "Ekonomicheskaya gazeta" (Economic gazette), No. 41, 1965, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed.): op. cit., Volume 2; p. 54).
"The reconstruction of existing enterprises... will be fully financed from profits, amortisation (i.e., depreciation allowances -- WBB) and bank credits".
(V. Batyrev: "The Economic Reform and the Increasing Role of Credit", in: "Kommunist" (Communist). No. 2, 1966, in: M.E. Sharpe (Ed.): op. cit., Volume 2; p. 246).
"Credit is a much more advantageous way of financing than non-repayable budget funds...
Under the new conditions of economic management new enterprises will be built on credits supplied by the Stroibank... provided that the outlay be repaid within five years from the time the project goes into operation...
The reconstruction and extension of existing plants and factories will be financed partly from the profit and depreciation allowances for complete restoration of fixed assets and partly from Stroibank credits".
(V. Vorobyev: ibid.; p. 90-1).
"Investments in enlarging and modernising operating enterprises will be increasingly made on account of the production development fund and back credits. Moreover, industry's own resources and long-term bank credits will serve as sources of investment in new enterprises which recoup with their own profit the invested resources in periods of up to five years".
(T.S. Khachaturov: ibid,; p. 156).
"Investments are financed first of al l out of funds owned by the enterprises, organisations and construction sites. If these are insufficienct, then bank credits are allocated".
(K.N. Plotnikov: ibid.; p. 217-8).
The basic reason why bank credit came to constitute such a very small proportion of investment was:
(V.N. Kulikov: ibid.; p. 61).
(V. Vorobyev: ibid.; p. 91).
(N. Fedorenko: "On the Elaboration of a System of Optimal Functioning of the Socialist Economy",, in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Problems of Economics), No. 6, 1972, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 15, No. 6; January 1973; p. 21).
"Cost accounting has essentially widened the sphere of self-sufficiency. Self-sufficiency means that an enterprise itself finances its current and long-term expenditures and obtains a profit on a scale which ensures extended socialist reproduction".
(P.G. Bunich: "Methods of Planning and Stimulation", in: "Soviet Economic Reform: Progres and Problems"; Moscow; 1972; p. 51-2).
The victory of internal financing over the borrowing from banks, savings banks and insurance institutions indicates... the decay of the role of banking capital. That decline is a universal trend...
The primacy of self-financing over borrowing is not the end of capitalism and is not even the end of finance capitalism. It merely indicates that the seat of finance capitalism has shifted from the banks to industry, or rather to a congruence of banks and industry".
(P. Neumann: "Behemoth: The Structure and Practice of National Socialism"; London; 1942; p. 261, 262).
(A.N. Kosygin: ibid.; p. 21).
"Budgetary allocations for this purpose (i.e., investment -- WBB) must be authorised by the USSR Council of Ministers".
(V. Vorobyev: ibid.; p. 246)
"Only in exceptional cases will the means (for investment -- WBB) come from the budget".
(V. Batyrev: ibid.; p. 246).
(T.S. Khachaturov: ibid.; p. 165).
In the European part of the USSR and in the Urals industrial development will largely follow the line of technical re-equipment and reconstruction of operating enterprises".
(A.N. Kosygin: "Guidelines for the Development of the National Economy of the USSR for 1976-1980", 25th Congress CPSU; Moscow; 1976, p. 72).
These types of investments may conventionally be called extensive (requiring new manpower) and intensive (which ensure a rise in labour productivity and release manpower)"
(T.S. Khachaturov: ibid.; p. 152).
"National income can grow mainly on account of additional investments, an increase in the work force as a whole and the number of persons employed in the sphere of material production -- this is the extensive method of development. But there is also another way -- the intensification of social production. This can be achieved by replacing existing equipment with new technically advanced machinery and by attaining, on the basis of new technology, a rise in labour productivity and a saving of material, manpower and financial resources. This way is more efficient and therefore preferable".
(D.A. Allakhverdyan: "National Income and Income Distribution in the USSR", in: "The Soviet Planned Economy"; Moscow; 1974; p. 85).
(T.S. Khachaturov: ibid.; p. 156).
"In view of the huge scale of investments great significance attaches to their economic efficiency, i.e., choosing the most favourable trends in construction, ensuring the biggest returns per unit of investments".
(K.N. Plotnikov: ibid.; p. 217).
1971-75: 42%
1976-80: ("planned"): 25%
("Soviet Economy Forges Ahead";
Moscow; 1973; p. 16).(A.N. Kosygin: ibid.; p. 11, 69).
This is, of course, in line with the practice of orthodox capitalist countries in conditions of monopoly, where maximum profitability often accrues from continuing to operate means of production after they have become obsolescent.
The decline in the growth rate of investment has been associated with a decline in the growth rate of industrial output:
1971-75: 47%
1975-80 ("planned"): 35-39%
("Soviet Economy Forges Ahead";
Moscow; 1973; p. 160). (A.N. Kosygin: ibid.; p. 29).
YEAR GROWTH RATE
1966-70: 41%
1971-75: 39%
1976-80 ("planned"): 24-28%
(D.A. Allakhverdyan: ibid.; p. 88); (A.N. Kosygin: ibid.; p. 29).