19: "Divide and Rule"
An important aspect of the material incentives system introduced under the "economic reform" is its utilisation to play off one worker, and one group of workers, against another. In fact, contemporary Soviet economists admit that the decisive factor in the "efficiency" of the system is not the size of the bonuses paid, but the differentiation in their size between individual workers, which enables the management to play off one worker against another:
(B. Gubin: "Raising the Efficiency of Socialist Economic Management"; Moscow; 1973; p. 79).
(P. Tabalov: "Switching Over to the New System", in: "Pravda" (Truth), October 27th., 1965, in: "The Soviet Economic Reform: Main Features and Aims"; Moscow; 1967; p. 119).
"Differentiating the rate of
pay for labour by regions and types of labour (male, female and so on),
it will be possible to influence in a planned manner the structure of utilising
labour resources".
(A.G. Aganbegyan: "Territorial
Planning and the Economic Reform", in: "Soviet Economic Reform:Progress
and Problems"; Moscow; 1972; p. 99).
A particularly unpleasant feature of "divide and rule" discussed in the previous section is the official encouragement of racist prejudices -- manifested in particular, in Soviet conditions, by a revival of that scourge of tsarist Russia, anti-Semitism.
In the days when Soviet society was socialist in character, the official position on anti-Semitism was one of outright denunciation and illegality:
Anti-Semitism is of advantage to the exploiters as a lightening conductor that deflects the blows aimed by the working people at capitalism. Anti-Semitism is dangerous for the working people as being a false path that leads them off the right road and lands them in the jungle. Hence Communists, as consistent internationalists, cannot but be irreconcilable, sworn enemies of anti-Semitism.
In the USSR anti-Semitism is punishable with the utmost severity of the law as a phenomenon deeply hostile to the Soviet system".
(J.V. Stalin: "Anti-Semitism", in: "Works", Volume 13; Moscow; 1955; p. 30).
This anti-Semitism, which is created by the Party bosses,... finds fertile ground among people who are looking for a scapegoat on which to vent their frustrations with the regime.
The State and the Party use anti-Semitism as a safety-valve. The regime still encourages and old saying from Czarist times, 'Save Russia, boot the Yids'. Even in the camp where there were water shortages, anti-semitic prisoners would come out with an old song about the stinking Jews drinking it all.
Every year anti-Semitism in the Soviet Union gets worse. The children of Jews are no longer admitted to higher institutions of learning -- or if they are, it's through bribery and corruption."
(M. Shtern: "Jew in Gulag: Shtern's story", in: "The Observer", April 24th., 1977; p. 10).
"The camp authorities inculcate nationalistic conflicts and agitate other inmates against the Jews. KGB Captains Maruzan and Ivkin stress in their conversation with non-Jewish inmates that all nationalities of the USSR must take a stand against Jews, particularly in labour camps. The administration provokes anti-Jewish incidents, utilizes informers and spies, and uses false witnesses in order to be able to impose additional punishment upon the Jews. Inmates who have had contact with Jews are summoned for discussions during which anti-Semitic sentiments are expressed and they are told that protest against arbitrariness in camp rules are profitable to the Zionists".
("A Perm Camp", in: Amnesty International: "Prisoners of Conscience in the USSR: Their Treatment and Conditions", London; 1975; p. 80).
"Audiences in Russia are currently being shown a specially made film which is deliberately and wildly anti-Semitic. The film is called 'Things Secret and Things Obvious' and it is a vicious attack on Jews. It is a compilation of newsreel film and reconstructed scenes, and it attacks Jews from the 1917 revolution to the present day. Accompanying the pictures is a particularly nasty commentary saying such contentious and unpleasant things as: "Jewish capitalists assisted Hitler a great deal in coming to power". It also make great play of the fact that it was a Jewess, Fanny Kaplan, who once tried to kill Lenin...
The film... has been produced by the Moscow Central Studio of Documentary films".
("The Guardian", March 29th., 1977; p. 11).
According to Marxism-Leninism, corporatism exists in capitalist society when independent trade unions representing the economic interests of the working class have been replaced by "corporations" of which both capitalist managements and employed workers are members.
In Nazi Germany the Labour Front was a classic "corporation". It included
( R.A. Brady: "The Spirit and Structure of German Fascism"; London; 1937; p. 125).
(R. Ley: Address to the Foreign Press, March 7th., 1935, in: R.A. Brady: ibid.; p. 124).
(R.A. Brady: ibid.; p. 41).
Like the Labour Front, too, the Soviet "trade unions" do not participate in collective bargaining on such important questions as wage levels, since -- as has been demonstrated in Section 12: "The Price of Labour Power" -- these are determined by the state.
As in the later days of the fascist regime in Spain, Soviet workers are responding to Soviet "corporatism" by setting up independent trade unions to defend and improve their conditions of work:
With the news of the imprisoned workers came an appeal to Amnesty form the Association of Free Trade Unions of Workers in the Soviet Union, already more than 200 strong, to forward their application to the International Labour Organisation (ILO) in Geneva to be given ILO recognition".
("USSR Jails Trade Unionists", in: "British Amnesty", No. 25; April 1978; p. 1).
(ibid.; p. 1).
A strike last year reduced the working hours. And for the past week workers have been picketing the factory to force the ten Soviet bosses to come to the negotiating table. True to board room form the bosses are refusing to comment, but the strikers sense victory because the managing director has just made a secret trip to Moscow, presumably to discuss the effects of the dispute on the dividend".
("Striking Out", in: "The Guardian",
April 27th., 1978; p. 15).
According to Marxism-Leninism, a certain level of social services (for example, in the fields of education and health) is necessary for the effective operation of a modern capitalist society. Unhealthy workers, without a minimum of education, are incapable of maximising the creation of profit.
Expenditure by the Soviet state on education, the health service, sickness benefits, children's allowances, pensions, recreational and holiday facilities, housing construction, vocational training etc., are drawn from what is termed social consumption funds. These funds account for some 17-20% of the income of the average working class family. (Y.L. Manevich: "Wages Systems", in: "The Soviet Planned Economy"; Moscow; 1974; p. 259).
Some 60% of Soviet state expenditure in connection with social services takes the form of monetary benefits, some 40% that of services. (Y.L. Manevich: ibid.; p. 263).
The aim of a capitalist class, however, is to keep the level of social services at the minimum level consistent with maximum profitability and social stability of the social system and to make a higher level of services available only on a payment (and profit making) basis.
The Soviet capitalist class pursues both these aims.
The growth rate of payments from social consumption funds has fallen consistently since the "economic reform", as follows:
1966-70: 53%
1871-75: 40%
1976-80 ("planned"): 26-30%
("Soviet Economy Forges Ahead"; Moscow; 1973; p. 70).
(A.N. Kosygin: "Guidelines for the Development of the National Ecoomy of the USSR for 1976-80", 25th. Congress CPSU; Moscow; 1976; p. 25).
The development of educational and health services that operate on a payment and profit-making basis has been a feature of the Soviet social system since the "economic reform":
(V. Azar & I. Pletnikova: "On the Question of the Classification and Full Assessment of Services in Personal Consumption", in: "Nauchnye doklady vysshei shkoly: Ekonomicheskie nauki" (Scientific Reports of Higher Schools: Economic Science). No. 11, 1973, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 17, No. 2; June 1974; p. 55).
The volume of paid services will grow by 47% during the five year plan.. The volume of unpaid services will increase by 32% during the five year period".
(V. Komarov: "The Service Sector and its Structure", in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Problems of Economics), No. 2, 1973, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 16, No. 3; p. 8,9).
(V.Komarov: ibid.; p. 9).
(V. Komarov: ibid.; p. 9).
(V. Rutgaiser: "A Comprehensive Plan for the Development of the Service Sector", in: "Planovoe khoziaistvo" (Planned Economy), No. 2, 1973, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 16, No. 5; September 1975; p. 49).
(K. Marx: "Capital", Volume 1; London; 1974; p. 168-9).
The first and most widespread assumption is that all expenditure for education should necessarily come out of the surplus product. But this is not true...
In the expenditures for education, it is necessary to discriminate between those made by the government and those made by parents or the pupil himself".
(V. Zhamin: "Economics and Education", in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Problems of Economics), No. 2, 1967, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 10, No. 5; September 1967; p. 48, 49-50).
Accordingly, on June 1st., 1962 a joint resolution of the Central Committee of the CPSU and the Government instructed republic administrations to prohibit the building of private houses in towns with a population of more than 100,000.
At the same time citizens in need of a home were encouraged to invest in housing co-operatives which, with the aid of state credits, would build multi-storey blocks of flats in such large towns. Those who could afford a down-payment of 40% (1,000 to 3,000 rubles, depending on the type of accommodation) would in this way have the possibility of moving into a new flat within a few years of joining the co-operative, without having to wait their turn on the state housing list.
These measures brought about a relative increase in the proportion of dwellings being built by the state and by housing co-operatives, and a relative decrease in the proportion being built privately:
Proportion of Housing Space
Built
1961-65 1966-70
BY THE STATE
58.5%
61.5%
BY HOUSING COOPERATIVES 2.7% 6.5%
PRIVATELY 19.2% 14.0%
BY COLLECTIVE FARMS &
COLLECTIVE FARMERS
19.6% 18.0%
("Narodnoe khoziaistvo SSSR v 1970 godu" (The National Economy of the USSR in the Year 1970); Mosocw; 1971; in: H.W. Morton & R.L. Tokes: "Soviet Politics and Society in the 1970's"; New York; 1974; p. 181).
For urban housing this trend was considerably more marked:
Proportion of Housing Space Built
By housing co-operatives 10.7% 10.8%
Privately 24.4% 13.2% 9.3%
(Ibid.; p. 182).
State housing is, to date, a true social service in the contemporary Soviet Union, being subsidised by the state as to two-thirds of its construction and operating costs, with rents fixed at a nominal 3-4% of the income of the occupying families.
("Soviet Economy Forges Ahead"; Moscow; 1973; p. 207).
(P.S. Mstislavsky: "The Standard of Living", in: "The Soviet Planned Economy"; Moscow; 1974; p. 269).
Nevertheless, in line with other social services, the proportion of total capital investment devoted to housing has declined significantly in recent years:
1956-60: 23.2%
1961-65: 18.3%
1966-70: 17.0%
("Narodnoe khoziaistvo SSSR v 1970 godu" (The National Economy of the USSR in the Year 1970)); Moscow; 1971; in: H.W. Morton: op. cit., p. 168).
and the standard of state housing is admittedly low:
(E.G. Antosenkov: "The Availability of Housing and Personnel Turnover", in: "Izvestia sibirskogo otdelenya Akademy Nauk SSSR: Serila obshchestvennykh nauk" (Journal of the Siberian Section of the Academy of Sciences of the USSR; Social Science Series). No. 11, 1972, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 16, No. 3; July 1973; p. 59)
Since the "economic reform", every enterprise is required to set up out of its profits, in addition to a production development fund and an economic incentives fund, a fund for social and cultural undertakings and housing:
(V.M. Batyrev: "Commodity-Money Relations under Socialism", in: "The Soviet Planned Economy"; Moscow; 1974; p. 172).
Like the other two funds, the size of the fund for social and cultural undertakings and housing is dependent on the rate of profit made by the enterprise:
(S. Kamenitser: "The Experience of Industrial Management in the Soviet Union"; Moscow; 1975; p. 134).
At the same time, the fund is designed to assist the enterprise in competing for manpower and retaining it, by providing amenities such as housing to its employees that might not otherwise be available. This applies also when the fund is used to assist employees to purchase houses privately:
(E.G. Antosenkov: ibid,; p. 68-9).
The corporations' expenditure on welfare schemes.. is seen to 'produce the greatest material and ideological returns to the corporation'".
(W.G. Scott: "Human Relations' in Management", Homewood (USA); 1962; p. 368).
(N. Bogomolova: "Human Relations' Doctrine: Ideological Weapon of the Monopolies"; Moscow; 1973; p. 107).
(N.Y. Drogichinsky: "The Economic Reform in Action", in: "Soviet Economic Reform: Progress and Problems"; Moscow; 1972; p. 207).
(B. Khomeliansky: "The Sphere of Social and Economic Services and the Reproduction of Aggregate Labour Power", in: "Nauchnye doklady vysshei shkoly: Ekonomicheskie nauki" (Scientific Reports of Higher Schools: Economic Science), No. 4, 1972, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 16, No. 2; June 1973; p. 62-3).
Contemporary Soviet economists and politicians hold that harmony between man and his environment is possible only under a planned socialist or communist social system:
(K. Ananichev: "Environment: International Aspects"; Moscow; 1976; p. 30).
(N. Fedorenko & K. Gofman: "Problems of Optimisation of the Planning and Control of the Environment", in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Problems of Economics), No. 10, 1972, in: "Problems of Economics". Volume 15, No. 12; April 1973; p. 46).
The law calling for the re-cultivation of disturbed lands is not always observed in the prospecting and extracting of minerals and in urban, industrial and transport construction".
("Safeguard and Multiply Natural Wealth", in: "Planovoe khoziaistvo" (Planned Economy), No. 6, 1973, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 16, No. 11; March 1974; p. 32-33).
"In the Soviet Union and other socialist countries... there are violations of technology... and as a result unpurified gases are discharged into the atmosphere, unpurified waters are discharged into rivers and water basins, there is soil erosion, etc.".
(G. Khromushin: "Problems of Ecology", in: "Voprosy ekonomiki" (Problems of Economics), No. 8, 1973, in: "Problems of Economics", Volume 16, No. 11; March 1974; p. 53-54).
"For all the variety of causes behind the deterioration of the environment in the United States and the Soviet Union, both these countries are now faced with the practical need to check this process...
The harm caused to bodies of water by effluents from pulp-and-paper, chemical fibre, and other factories is well-known. Every day they discard thousands of tons of polluted water into rivers, lakes and seas. The damage caused by these effluents is incalculable".
(K. Ananichev: ibid.; p. 118, 123)
(L. Brezhnev: Report to the 24th. Congress CPSU, in: K. Ananichev: ibid.; p. 24).
For example, Soviet environmentalists generally agree that one of the two chief causes of atmospheric pollution is motor transport:
The chief sources of air pollution today are the power industry and motor transport".
(K. Ananichev: ibid.; p. 97, 120).
(K. Ananichev: ibid.; p. 97).
(K. Ananichev: ibid.; p. 97-8).
(K. Ananichev: ibid.; p. 121).
(N. Fedorenko & K. Gofman: ibid.; p. 45).